2018 Quadrennial Regulatory Review-Review of the Commission's Broadcast Ownership Rules

Published date28 February 2019
Citation84 FR 6741
Record Number2019-03278
SectionProposed rules
CourtFederal Communications Commission
Federal Register, Volume 84 Issue 40 (Thursday, February 28, 2019)
[Federal Register Volume 84, Number 40 (Thursday, February 28, 2019)]
                [Proposed Rules]
                [Pages 6741-6757]
                From the Federal Register Online via the Government Publishing Office [www.gpo.gov]
                [FR Doc No: 2019-03278]
                =======================================================================
                -----------------------------------------------------------------------
                FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
                47 CFR Part 73
                [MB Docket No. 18-349; FCC 18-179]
                2018 Quadrennial Regulatory Review--Review of the Commission's
                Broadcast Ownership Rules
                AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.
                ACTION: Proposed rule.
                -----------------------------------------------------------------------
                SUMMARY: In this document, the Commission's Notice of Proposed
                Rulemaking (NPRM) initiates the 2018 quadrennial review of its media
                ownership rules, launched pursuant to a requirement of the
                Telecommunications Act of 1996 (1996 Act) that the Commission review
                its media ownership rules every four years to determine whether they
                remain ``necessary in the public interest as the result of
                competition'' and to ``repeal or modify any determine[d] to be no
                longer in the public interest.'' The three rules currently subject to
                review are the Local Radio Ownership Rule, the Local Television
                Ownership Rule, and the Dual Network Rule. The NPRM seeks comment on
                whether, given the current state of the media marketplace, the
                Commission should retain, modify, or eliminate any of these rules. The
                NPRM also seeks comment on several proposals offered as potential pro-
                diversity initiatives.
                DATES: Comments due April 29, 2019. Reply comments due May 29, 2019.
                ADDRESSES: Interested parties may submit comments and replies,
                identified by MB Docket No. 18-349, by any of the following methods:
                 Federal eRulemaking Portal: http://www.regulations.gov.
                Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
                 Federal Communications Commission's website: http://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs/. Follow the instructions for submitting comments.
                 Mail: Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery,
                by commercial overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S.
                Postal Service mail (although the Commission continues to experience
                delays in receiving U.S. Postal Service mail). All filings must be
                addressed to the Commission's Secretary, Office of the Secretary,
                Federal Communications Commission.
                 For more detailed filing instructions, see the Procedural Matters
                section below.
                FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: Brendan Holland, Industry Analysis
                Division, Media Bureau, Brendan.Holland@fcc.gov (202) 418-2757.
                SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of the Commission's Notice
                of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM) in MB Docket No. 18-349; FCC 18-179,
                adopted on December 12, 2018, and released on December 13, 2018. The
                full text of this document is available for public inspection during
                regular business hours in the FCC Reference Center, 445 12th Street SW,
                Room CY-A257, Washington, DC 20554, or online at https://docs.fcc.gov/public/attachments/FCC-18-179A1.pdf. To request this document in
                accessible formats for people with disabilities (e.g., braille, large
                print, electronic files, audio format, etc.) or to request reasonable
                accommodations (e.g., accessible format documents, sign language
                interpreters, CART, etc.), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the
                FCC's Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-0530
                (voice), (202) 418-0432 (TTY).
                Synopsis
                 1. Background. Last year, the Commission completed its prior
                combined 2010/2014 review of its media ownership rules by adopting an
                Order on Reconsideration (2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on
                Reconsideration) of its initial Order (2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
                Order), a reconsideration that relaxed or eliminated several rules,
                including repeal of the previous bans on newspaper/broadcast and radio/
                television cross-ownership in a market. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
                Review Order on Reconsideration the Commission revised the Local
                Television Ownership Rule by eliminating the requirement that, in order
                to own two stations in a market, eight independent voices must remain
                in the market post-transaction, and concluded that it would consider,
                on a case-by-case basis, combinations that would otherwise be barred by
                the prohibition on ownership of two top-four ranked stations in a
                market. In eliminating and revising its rules, the Commission
                recognized the dynamic changes in the media marketplace and the wealth
                of information sources now available to consumers. The Commission also
                found that, while the record in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
                supported adoption of an incubator program to foster the entry of new
                and diverse voices in the broadcasting industry, the structure and
                implementation of such a program required further exploration.
                Accordingly, the Commission sought comment on these issues, and on
                August 2, 2018, adopted a Report and Order (Incubator Order)
                establishing an incubator program to foster new entry into the
                broadcasting industry. Under the program, an established broadcaster
                (i.e., incubating entity) will provide a new entrant or small
                broadcaster (i.e., incubated entity) with training, financing, and
                access to resources that would be otherwise inaccessible to these
                entities. In return for this support, the incubating entity can receive
                a waiver of the applicable Local Radio Ownership Rule that it can use
                either in the incubated market or in a comparable market within three
                years of the successful conclusion of a qualifying incubation
                relationship.
                 2. Multiple parties sought reconsideration and judicial review of
                the Commission's 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order, 2010/2014
                Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration and Incubator Order. The
                Third Circuit U.S. Court of Appeals has consolidated the petitions for
                judicial review of these Orders and its review is pending.
                 3. Local Radio Ownership Rule. The rule allows an entity to own:
                (1) Up to eight commercial radio stations in radio markets with at
                least 45 radio stations, no more than five of which may be in the same
                service (AM or FM); (2) up to seven commercial radio stations in radio
                markets with 30-44 radio stations, no more than four of which may be in
                the same service (AM or FM); (3) up to six commercial radio stations in
                radio markets with 15-29 radio stations, no more than four of which may
                be in the same service (AM or FM); and (4) up to five commercial radio
                stations in radio markets with 14 or fewer radio stations, no more than
                three of which may be in the same service (AM or FM), provided that the
                entity does not own more than 50 percent of the radio stations in the
                market unless the combination comprises not more than one AM and one FM
                station. When determining the total number of radio stations within a
                [[Page 6742]]
                market, only full-power commercial and noncommercial radio stations are
                counted for purposes of the rule. Radio markets are defined by Nielsen
                Audio where applicable and, in Puerto Rico, the contour-overlap
                methodology used in areas outside of defined and rated Nielsen Audio
                Metro markets.
                 4. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order, the Commission
                concluded that local radio ownership limits promoted competition, a
                public interest benefit providing a sufficient basis for retaining a
                local radio ownership rule. The Commission affirmed its previous
                finding that competitive local radio markets help promote viewpoint
                diversity and localism and are consistent with the Commission's goal of
                promoting minority and female broadcast station ownership. In the
                subsequent 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration, the
                Commission adopted a presumption, to be further considered in this 2018
                Quadrennial Review, in favor of waiving the Local Radio Ownership Rule
                for qualifying radio stations within embedded markets (i.e., smaller
                markets, as defined by Nielsen Audio, that are contained within the
                boundaries of a larger, parent Nielsen Audio Metro market) where the
                parent market currently has multiple embedded markets (i.e., New York
                and Washington, DC). Such a waiver would permit the applicant to comply
                with ownership limits determined by examining only the embedded market,
                and not both the embedded and parent markets. Stations would qualify
                for waivers under two conditions: (1) Compliance with the numerical
                ownership limits using the Nielsen Audio Metro methodology in each
                embedded market, and (2) compliance with the ownership limits using the
                contour-overlap methodology applicable to undefined markets in lieu of
                the Commission's current parent market analysis.
                 5. The Commission seeks comment generally on all aspects of the
                Local Radio Ownership Rule, including whether the rule remains
                necessary in the public interest to promote competition and
                specifically, whether there have been any changes in the marketplace
                since the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review that would affect this
                determination. The Commission also seeks comment on whether, in today's
                radio marketplace, the rule remains necessary to promote other
                Commission policy goals such as viewpoint diversity, localism, and
                female and minority broadcast ownership. Commenters are asked to
                explain in detail and support with evidence their reasons for any
                recommended rule changes. If the rule is retained, the Commission will
                analyze relevant parts of the rule to examine whether each part remains
                necessary in the public interest due to competition or whether it
                should be modified or eliminated. Thus, the Commission seeks comment on
                each of the specific aspects of the rule's operation, including the
                relevant product market, market size tiers, numerical limits, and AM/FM
                subcaps, to assess whether these subparts remain necessary or whether
                any of all of them should be modified or eliminated. If the rule is
                retained but modified, the Commission seeks comment on whether and how
                the rule changes should apply to any pending applications. The
                Commission also seeks comment on whether to make permanent the interim
                contour-overlap methodology used to determine ownership limits in areas
                outside the boundaries of defined Nielsen Audio Metro markets, and on
                the issue of embedded market transactions.
                 6. In anticipation of further consideration of the presumption in
                favor of waiving the Local Radio Ownership Rule for radio stations
                within embedded markets, the National Association of Broadcasters (NAB)
                submitted a proposal to, among other things, allow an entity in the top
                75 Nielsen Audio Metro markets to own or control up to eight commercial
                FM stations and unlimited AM stations in any of those markets. NAB also
                proposed that entities in those markets should be permitted to own up
                to two additional FM stations if they participated in the Commission's
                incubator program. NAB also proposed eliminating all limits on FM and
                AM ownership in all other markets. NAB claimed that these rule
                relaxations remove constraints on radio broadcasters' ability to
                compete on a level playing field in today's digital audio world where,
                NAB claimed the Commission cannot ignore, broadcast radio dominance has
                declined relative to streaming services such as Pandora and Spotify,
                satellite radio, podcasts, Facebook and You Tube, described as
                ``multiple major sources of competition for both listeners and
                advertisers in the audio marketplace.'' Thus, according to NAB, the
                more relevant factor for listeners has become where services can be
                accessed, which is now the same for radio and other services, rather
                than where services are headquartered. NAB added that allowing radio
                owners to achieve economies of scale and scope would enable them to
                improve their informational and entertainment programming. Other radio
                broadcasters similarly claimed that digital competitors such as Google
                and Facebook enjoy perceived advantages in ability to target
                advertising, do not need to employ local advertising salesforces, and
                had therefore captured significant shares of the local advertising
                market to the detriment of local broadcast radio. Other parties argued
                in opposition to NAB's proposal that allowing radio broadcasters to buy
                more stations would not help them compete against internet services
                such as Google and Facebook, the size of station portfolios had little
                relevance to dollars allocated to free radio, advertisers did not view
                radio and internet services as comparable, and radio remains the
                preferred audio medium for entertainment and local news.
                 7. The Commission received many additional comments in response to
                a request for updated information on the status of competition in the
                marketplace for the delivery of audio programming in seeking to prepare
                a biennial marketplace report for Congress, comments which are
                incorporated into the record of this 2018 Quadrennial Review. NAB
                provided information and statistical data purporting to show how
                fragmented the listening market has become, and a coalition of radio
                broadcasters claimed that radio listening has shrunk as audiences
                divide their time among other audio providers not subject to the same
                regulatory burdens as radio broadcasters. Other radio station owners
                asserted that the Commission's ownership limits prevent them from
                achieving the economies of scale and scope they need to compete with
                satellite radio and online audio services. On the other hand,
                coalitions representing musicians, recording artists, and
                representatives of the music industry argued that AM/FM radio continues
                to dominate the audio marketplace and that experience shows that
                consolidation in the radio industry harms small broadcasters and leads
                to the homogenization of programming.
                 8. Market Definition. The Commission concluded in the 2010/2014
                Quadrennial Review Order that the broadcast radio listening market
                remains the relevant product market for purposes of the Local Radio
                Ownership Rule and declined to expand its definition of the market to
                include non-broadcast audio sources, such as satellite radio and online
                audio services. The Commission's based this conclusion on the fact that
                broadcast radio stations provide ``free, over-the-air programming
                tailored to the needs of the stations' local markets,'' while in
                [[Page 6743]]
                contrast, satellite radio is a subscription service, online audio
                requires an internet connection, and neither typically provides
                programming responsive to local needs and interests. Similarly, in
                evaluating a broadcast radio merger of Entercom Communications and CBS
                in November 2017, the Department of Justice (DOJ) also considered the
                radio market, concluding that ``[m]any local and national advertisers
                consider English-language broadcast radio to be a particularly
                effective or important means to reach their desired customers, and do
                not consider advertisements on other media, including non-English-
                language broadcast radio, digital music streaming services (such as
                Pandora), and television, to be reasonable substitutes.''
                 9. The Commission now seeks comment on these differing perspectives
                of the state of the audio marketplace and on whether and how these
                perspectives should affect its understanding of the market for purposes
                of the Local Radio Ownership Rule. Should the Commission take DOJ's
                finding on the radio market into account and if so, how? Should the
                Commission continue to consider only local broadcast radio stations for
                purposes of the Local Radio Ownership Rule or should it revise its
                market definition to include other audio sources? Do local radio
                stations face direct competition today from satellite radio and online
                audio services? To what extent has radio's ability to attract listeners
                and advertisers been affected by satellite radio and online audio? Do
                advertisers view satellite radio and audio streaming services as
                substitutes for advertising on broadcast radio? How should the impact
                of internet services like Google and Facebook on local advertising
                markets factor into our consideration of the Local Radio Ownership
                Rule? Do consumers view non-broadcast audio services as meaningful
                substitutes for local radio stations? Do non-broadcast audio services
                provide programming that responds to the needs and interests of local
                markets? Does radio's free, over-the-air availability make it unique or
                non-substitutable in the audio marketplace? To what extent, if any,
                should the Commission consider the deployment of In Band on Channel
                digital radio technology and its role in enabling station owners to
                expand their program offerings and increase their economies of scale
                and scope? If the Commission were to revise its market definition, what
                non-broadcast sources should it include, and how should it count them
                or otherwise factor them into its rule for purposes of determining
                market size tiers and numerical limits? Could or should the Commission
                subtract from any consideration of non-broadcast sources the amount of
                online audio that listeners in a local market stream from over-the-air
                radio broadcasts? How would an expanded definition better serve
                Commission policy goals, if at all?
                 10. Market Size Tiers. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order,
                the Commission retained the Local Radio Ownership Rule's longstanding
                approach of imposing numerical ownership limits based on market size
                tiers and determining market size by counting the number of commercial
                and noncommercial radio stations within the market. The Commission
                declined to change the rule to treat embedded markets as separate
                markets. In addition, the Commission kept in place the demarcations of
                the four tiers set by Congress in 1996, which draw the lines among
                Nielsen Audio Metro markets at 45 plus, 30-44, 15-29, and 14 or fewer
                radio stations, including noncommercial stations. The Commission seeks
                comment on whether it should retain this approach of using market size
                tiers, and if it does so, whether the current demarcations should
                remain. Is there any reason to discontinue including noncommercial
                radio stations in market counts? How well has the rule's tiered
                structure served the rule's purposes, and does it promote the policy
                goals of competition, localism, and viewpoint diversity in today's
                radio marketplace? NAB's proposal would divide radio markets into only
                two tiers--the top 75 Nielsen Audio Metro markets and all other markets
                (i.e., Nielsen Audio Metro markets outside of the top 75 and all
                undefined markets). What would be the advantages and disadvantages of
                creating a different number of tiers, including moving from a four-
                tiered to a two-tiered approach? If the Commission were to collapse
                four tiers into two, should it draw the line where NAB proposes?
                Commenters are invited to offer alternative proposals for a tiered
                approach or for a different type of approach altogether. For example,
                if the Commission changed from tiers based on station counts, should it
                consider tiers based on advertising revenue, or some other factor,
                rather than using Nielsen's Audio Metro market rankings as NAB
                proposes, which are based on population? Would advertising revenue
                provide a sufficiently stable measurement and how would such a
                measurement fit with defining the relevant product market as the
                broadcast radio listening market? How would the Commission and
                potential applicants obtain reliable advertising revenue data for all
                radio stations? Should the Commission factor non-broadcast audio
                sources in any tiered approach, and if so, how should it do so? For
                example: (1) If the Commission modifies its current tiers or creates
                new tiers, should it account for variations across markets in broadband
                access and adoption rates; (2) should the Commission treat fixed and
                mobile or wired and wireless broadband the same; and (3) how granularly
                can and should the Commission measure listening rates for satellite
                radio and online audio services?
                 11. In addition, should any modifications to the current tiered
                approach affect how the Commission applies the rule to areas outside
                the boundaries of defined Nielsen Audio Metro markets, and if so, how?
                NAB proposes removing all radio ownership limits for undefined areas.
                Would NAB's proposal be consistent with Commission policy goals or
                would it lead to excessive consolidation in those outside areas, and
                what alternative approach could the Commission take in areas of the
                country that are undefined by Nielsen Audio? Further, the contour-
                overlap methodology has been successfully applied on an interim basis
                to undefined markets for years and the Commission previously rejected
                arguments that it permitted too much consolidation in certain markets.
                Is this approach the most effective and practical for determining
                ownership limits in areas outside defined Nielsen Audio Metro markets
                and should the Commission therefore make it permanent? Any commenters
                opposed to adopting the contour-overlap methodology on a permanent
                basis should explain their reasoning and propose a detailed alternative
                supported by evidence.
                 12. Numerical Limits. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order,
                the Commission declined to relax or tighten the numerical limits
                restricting the number of radio stations an entity may own within a
                radio market. The Commission seeks comment on whether it is necessary
                as a result of competition to maintain the numerical limits for any or
                all of the market size tiers. If the Commission retains existing market
                tiers, are existing limits restricting the number of radio stations an
                entity may own within a radio market set appropriately for each of the
                market size tiers? Do the current limits adequately prevent a radio
                broadcaster from amassing excessive local market power? Conversely, do
                they permit sufficient growth to enable radio broadcasters to
                [[Page 6744]]
                obtain the additional assets they may need to improve the quality of
                their service? Commenters should provide concrete, actual examples of
                markets where the current limits are either too restrictive or too
                lenient, explain how those examples typify other markets in that tier,
                and specify the benefits to those markets that would be gained by
                revising the limits.
                 13. The Commission also seeks comment on whether it should account
                for the different signal strengths of radio stations by weighing
                different classes of radio stations differently for purposes of
                applying the numerical limits. For example, the Commission could
                consider a Class A AM station to be worth two stations, whereas a Class
                D AM station could be counted as one half a station. What would be the
                costs and benefits of such an approach? What values should be accorded
                to the different classes of radio stations if the Commission adopts
                such an approach? The Commission previously considered a proposal to
                assign different values to radio stations of different classes for
                purposes of determining market size tiers and seeks comment on
                assigning varying weights to different classes of radio stations when
                applying the numerical limits.
                 14. In addition, the Commission seeks comment on NAB's proposal to
                maintain the eight-station limit for the top 75 Nielsen Audio Metro
                markets but to apply it only to FM stations, thereby allowing unlimited
                AM ownership. NAB further proposes allowing an owner in the top 75
                Nielson Audio Metro markets to acquire up to two additional FM stations
                if it participates in (and, the Commission assumes, successfully
                completes) the incubator program. For all other markets, NAB urges the
                elimination of numerical limits for both FM and AM services. The
                Commission seeks comment on all aspects of NAB's proposed changes to
                the numerical limits and invites alternative proposals. What would be
                the likely effects of removing FM limits in most markets? What would be
                the likely effects of allowing unlimited AM ownership across all
                markets? Would such actions, on balance, promote competition by
                enabling owners to increase their assets, or would they harm
                competition and/or ownership diversity by driving smaller broadcasters,
                including minority and women owners, from the marketplace? How would
                viewpoint diversity and localism be affected? The Incubator Order
                rewards successful incubation of a radio station with one waiver per
                market to exceed the applicable ownership limit by one station and
                allows participants to use no more than one reward waiver per market.
                NAB submitted its proposal to maintain the eight-station limit for the
                top 75 Nielsen Audio Metro markets before the Commission adopted the
                Incubator Order, so it is unclear whether NAB is suggesting that
                successful incubation of one station should result in a waiver for two
                stations or successful incubation of two stations should entitle an
                owner to acquire two stations above the limit within the same market.
                The Commission seeks comment on both possible interpretations.
                 15. AM/FM Subcaps. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order, the
                Commission retained the Local Radio Ownership Rule's AM/FM subcaps,
                which prevent a broadcaster from owning more than five AM or five FM
                stations in markets in the largest market tier, four AM or four FM
                stations in markets in the two middle-sized tiers, or three AM or three
                FM stations in markets in the smallest tier. The Commission seeks
                comment on whether the AM/FM subcaps remain necessary and whether its
                previous reasons for maintaining subcaps are still valid. For example,
                have subcaps promoted market entry? Are subcaps still necessary given
                the Commission's efforts to revitalize AM radio or has the disparity
                between the FM and AM services been narrowed to an extent that the
                subcaps could be relaxed or eliminated? Since its 2010/2014 Quadrennial
                Review, the Commission has granted over 1,000 applications to acquire
                and relocate FM translators to rebroadcast AM stations. Should the
                expanded and improved coverage of those AM stations affect the analysis
                of subcaps? Conversely, data from the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
                indicated that the transition to digital radio actually exacerbated the
                divide between the services because AM stations have been slower to
                adopt digital radio technology. What is the import of the current
                status of the digital radio transition for evaluating the subcaps? If
                subcaps continue to promote competition or ownership diversity, or
                otherwise serve the public interest, are they currently set at the
                appropriate levels?
                 16. If the Commission revises the Local Radio Ownership Rule,
                should the modified rule include AM or FM subcaps, and if so, how
                should they be applied? NAB's proposal essentially would eliminate AM
                subcaps in all markets and retain FM subcaps in only the top 75
                markets. NAB does not explain why it would distinguish the FM service
                for restricted ownership in the top markets rather than limit the total
                number of radio stations in those markets regardless of service, and
                the Commission seeks comment on whether the proposal is supported by
                technical or marketplace differences between the services. In a letter
                filed shortly after NAB submitted its proposal, the owner of a network
                of AM stations argued that removing and/or relaxing FM subcaps would
                harm the AM service by facilitating the migration of content to the FM
                service. Concurring with that view, iHeartMedia urges the Commission to
                loosen restrictions on AM ownership while retaining the existing FM
                subcaps, arguing that doing so would be consistent with the
                Commission's efforts to revitalize AM radio. Considering these
                competing positions, the Commission seeks comment on what limits, if
                any, should apply to AM and FM ownership, whether to retain the current
                market size tiers and numerical limits, and on whether and how any
                proposed revisions to the Local Radio Ownership Rule should include
                such limits.
                 17. Embedded Markets. Owners of radio stations in embedded markets
                within a parent market, which currently exist only in New York and
                Washington, DC, must comply with the Local Radio Ownership Rule's
                numerical limits for both the embedded market and the parent market. In
                response to the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Further Notice of Proposed
                Rulemaking (FNPRM), Connoisseur Media argued that because radio
                stations within different embedded markets within a parent market have
                little or no contour overlap and may reach different populations, the
                Commission's analysis of a proposed acquisition in one embedded market
                should not include stations owned in the other embedded markets within
                the same parent market. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on
                Reconsideration, the Commission declined to adopt an across-the-board
                change to its embedded market methodology, but adopted a waiver
                standard whereby embedded market transactions in markets with multiple
                embedded markets would be presumed to be in the public interest if they
                met a two-prong test proposed by Connoisseur: (1) As with the
                Commission's current methodology for embedded markets, a radio station
                owner seeking a rule waiver must comply with the applicable numerical
                ownership limit in each embedded market using the Nielsen Audio Metro
                methodology; and (2) instead of then also demonstrating compliance with
                the applicable numerical ownership limit based on the Commission's
                parent
                [[Page 6745]]
                market analysis, the applicant must show that it also complies with the
                ownership limits as determined by the contour-overlap methodology
                ordinarily applicable in undefined markets. The Commission adopted this
                presumptive waiver standard on an interim basis pending the outcome of
                this 2018 Quadrennial Review proceeding.
                 18. Accordingly, the Commission seeks comment on how to address the
                issue of embedded market transactions. If the Commission retains a
                Local Radio Ownership Rule, how should it apply going forward to radios
                station in markets that contain multiple embedded markets, currently
                New York and Washington, DC? Should the presumptive waiver standard
                become permanent? Should it be modified in any way? Should it apply to
                all current and future markets that contain multiple embedded markets,
                or should its application be limited to the two existing parent markets
                with multiple embedded markets? How do competition, diversity, and
                localism considerations affect the question? Embedded market
                designations can be updated and modified by Nielsen Audio as market
                conditions change, and Nielsen Audio's radio station customers can
                request the designation of a new embedded market. How could the
                Commission guard against purchasers taking advantage of an anticipated
                designation of a new embedded market in a manner that would thwart the
                purpose of the current ownership limits? For example, in the event that
                Nielsen Audio creates new, additional situations with multiple embedded
                markets within a larger parent market, should there be a waiting period
                before applicants can take advantage of that change in circumstance,
                similar to the waiting period applicable to changes in the stations
                reported as ``home'' to a Nielsen Audio Metro market? If the Commission
                adopts any change to its approach to embedded markets, should the
                change also apply to markets with a single embedded market? Is there a
                distinction between markets with one embedded market and markets with
                multiple embedded markets such that the Commission should vary its
                approach between those situations?
                 19. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration,
                the Commission expressed its intent to consider in this 2018
                Quadrennial Review an alternate NAB proposal that stations licensed in
                embedded markets with signal coverage of less than 50 percent of the
                parent market's population not be considered part of the parent market
                for purposes of local ownership limit compliance calculations. The
                Commission seeks comment on whether it should adopt such an approach or
                any other across-the-board rule changes regarding embedded markets. Is
                there a need to implement a rule change that carves out a blanket
                exception to the current methodology given that there are only two
                parent markets containing multiple embedded markets? Or is a permanent
                presumptive waiver standard an adequate solution given how narrow its
                use is likely to be? The Commission seeks comment on the potential
                advantages and disadvantages of these various approaches and invites
                proposals for other ways to address embedded market transactions.
                 20. Minority and Female Ownership. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
                Review Order, the Commission found the current Local Radio Ownership
                Rule to be consistent with its goal of promoting minority and female
                ownership of broadcast radio stations, observing that the rule, while
                competition-based, indirectly promotes viewpoint diversity by
                facilitating ``the presence of independently owned broadcast radio
                stations in the local market, thereby increasing the likelihood of a
                variety of viewpoints and preserving ownership opportunities for new
                entrants.'' It pointed to AM subcaps in particular as elements of the
                rule that foster new entry. Because available data did not show that
                stricter limits would increase minority and female radio ownership,
                however, the Commission chose not to tighten the rule. Similarly, the
                Commission found no indication of a causal link between Congress'
                loosening of local radio limits in 1996 and the increase in ownership
                diversity since then that would justify loosening the rules. The
                Commission seeks comment on whether any new information has become
                available that would cause us to reevaluate these conclusions. The
                Commission also seeks comment on how retaining or modifying the Local
                Radio Ownership Rule might affect broadcast radio ownership and entry
                by small business owners, if at all.
                 21. Local Television Ownership Rule. The Local Television Ownership
                Rule allows an entity to own up to two television stations in the same
                Nielsen Designated Market Area (DMA) (a group of counties forming an
                exclusive geographic area to which the Nielsen Company assigns each
                broadcast television station) if: (1) The digital noise limited service
                contours (NLSCs) of the stations (as determined by Sec. 73.622(e) of
                the Commission's rules) do not overlap; or (2) at the time the
                application to acquire or construct the station(s) is filed, at least
                one of the stations is not ranked among the top-four stations in the
                DMA, based on the most recent all-day (9 a.m.-midnight) audience share,
                as measured by Nielsen Media Research or by any comparable
                professional, accepted audience ratings service. With respect to the
                latter provision--the Top-Four Prohibition--an applicant may request
                that the Commission examine the facts and circumstances in a market
                regarding a particular transaction and, based on the showing made by
                the applicant in a particular case, make a finding that permitting an
                entity to directly or indirectly own, operate, or control two top-four
                television stations licensed in the same DMA would serve the public
                interest, convenience, and necessity. The Commission considers showings
                that the Top-Four Prohibition should not apply due to specific
                circumstances in a local market or with respect to a specific
                transaction on a case-by-case basis.
                 22. The Commission found in the 2018 Quadrennial Review Order on
                Reconsideration that local television ownership limits remained
                necessary to promote competition among broadcast stations in local
                television markets, finding that such competition leads stations to
                invest in better and more locally tailored programming and to compete
                for advertising revenue and retransmission consent fees. The Commission
                also determined, however, that the existing rule required modification
                to ensure that television broadcasters could achieve efficiencies to
                make such improvements in an evolving video marketplace. The Commission
                therefore repealed the provision of the previous rule requiring at
                least eight independently owned television stations to remain in a DMA
                after any station acquisition in the DMA, finding that this Eight-
                Voices test was unsupported by the record or reasoned analysis and was
                no longer necessary in the public interest. The Commission also added
                flexibility to the application of the Top-Four Prohibition by adopting
                the case-by-case analysis mentioned above.
                 23. First, the Commission seeks comment on whether the current
                version of the Local Television Ownership Rule is necessary in the
                public interest as a result of competition. In earlier media ownership
                reviews, broadcasters argued that local television ownership
                restrictions prevent them from competing effectively, while other
                commenters supported retention of limits based on the need to prevent
                excessive consolidation of television stations due to the unique nature
                of their free, over-
                [[Page 6746]]
                the-air programming provided on spectrum licensed for public benefit.
                The Commission seeks comment on how developments in the video
                programming industry since the last quadrennial review have affected
                whether the Local Television Ownership Rule is necessary as a result of
                competition and to promote localism and viewpoint diversity among local
                broadcast television stations. The Commission seeks comment on whether
                promoting competition among television stations in local viewing
                markets continues to be the proper framework within which to consider
                the rule, and if so, what forms of competition it should take into
                account under such a framework. For instance, how, if at all, should
                the Commission consider competition among television stations for
                viewers, advertisers, retransmission consent fees, network affiliation,
                the provision of local news or other programming, the production or
                acquisition of programming, innovation, or any other form of
                competition?
                 24. The Commission also seeks comment on whether the Local
                Television Ownership Rule is necessary to promote localism or viewpoint
                diversity. The Commission has previously stated that a competition-
                based rule, while not designed specifically to promote localism or
                viewpoint diversity, may still have such an effect. Has the prior
                reliance on competition as the primary policy goal of the Local
                Television Ownership Rule also served as a proxy for preserving a
                certain level of localism or viewpoint diversity in local television
                markets that might otherwise be lost were we to find the rule no longer
                necessary for competition purposes?
                 25. The Commission seeks comment on whether a competition-based
                Local Television Ownership Rule promotes the production or provision of
                local programming. Localism has been a cornerstone of the Commission's
                broadcast regulation for decades, with the Commission finding that
                broadcast licensees have an obligation to air programming that is
                responsive to the needs and interests of their communities of license.
                Does promoting competition among broadcast stations incentivize
                stations to produce and improve local programming? Could or does
                competition from non-broadcast video sources, which have no local
                programming requirements, create the same incentives to produce and
                improve local programming?
                 26. If the Commission decides to retain the Local Television
                Ownership Rule, it will analyze the relevant parts of the rule to
                examine whether each particular provision similarly remains necessary
                in the public interest as a result of competition or whether it should
                be modified or eliminated. Thus, the Commission seeks comment on
                specific aspects of the rule's operation, including the relevant
                product market, numerical limits, and the Top-Four Prohibition, to
                assess whether these subparts remain necessary or whether any or all of
                them should be modified or eliminated. The Commission also asks whether
                developments in the video programming industry involving multicasting,
                satellite stations, low power stations, and the next generation
                transmission standard have any implications on the Local Television
                Ownership Rule or its subparts.
                 27. Market Definition. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on
                Reconsideration, the Commission found that a rule to preserve
                competition among local broadcast television stations was still
                warranted, but also noted that it was not free to retain the rule
                without adjustments to account for marketplace changes outside the
                local broadcast television market. The Commission also found that non-
                broadcast video offerings do not serve as meaningful substitutes for
                local broadcast television, and noted that video programming delivered
                by multichannel video programming distributors (MVPDs) is generally
                uniform across all markets, as is programming provided by online video
                distributors (OVDs). The Commission stated that unlike local broadcast
                stations, MVPDs and OVDs were not likely to make programming decisions
                based on conditions or preferences in local markets, but indicated that
                this conclusion could change in a future proceeding with a different
                record.
                 28. The Commission now seeks comment on relevant marketplace
                changes and whether and how it should take such changes into account.
                The Commission seeks comment on the appropriate product market for
                reviewing the Local Television Ownership Rule, including whether to
                include more than broadcast video programming and what market
                participants to consider. In light of the evolving video marketplace,
                the Commission also seeks comment on its prior findings in the 2010/
                2014 Quadrennial Review Order, and whether and to what extent non-
                broadcast sources of video programming should be considered competitors
                to broadcast television stations. Do consumers consider broadcast
                television to be interchangeable with other sources of programming? If
                so, what other sources of video programming should be included in the
                analysis of a local product market? What factors should the Commission
                consider in analyzing non-broadcast sources of video programming?
                Should the Commission distinguish between linear (scheduled) and non-
                linear (i.e., video-on-demand) distributors of video? In which product
                markets, if any, do non-broadcast video programmers compete with
                broadcast television programmers? Does broadcast television offer any
                programming for which there is no substitute available from non-
                broadcast video programmers? Based on Nielsen and NAB data, the
                Commission noted in the Eighteenth Video Competition Report the
                increasing number of households relying on broadcast rather than MVPD
                service. To what extent do consumers rely on broadcast television as
                their primary, or only, source of video programming? The Commission
                previously noted that broadband penetration is relevant when
                considering whether on-line platforms are meaningful substitutes for
                local broadcast. Is the availability of non-broadcast video comparable
                to that of broadcast television? Do viewers rely on or consume
                programming from local broadcast stations in a manner different from
                other sources of, potentially, non-local video programming? In
                addition, do any non-broadcast video programmers make programming
                decisions based on local markets or the actions of individual local
                television stations (i.e., a cable operator deciding to carry local
                sporting events not covered by the local broadcaster)?
                 29. The Commission also found in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
                Order that arguments by broadcasters that advertisers no longer
                distinguish between local broadcast television and non-broadcast video
                programming when deciding how to spend on local advertising were not
                supported by the record. Thus, the Commission seeks comment on whether
                and to what extent non-broadcast sources of video programming should be
                considered competitors to broadcast television stations. The Commission
                also asks how advertisers select between local broadcast and non-
                broadcast sources of programming and seeks studies and data that it can
                use to assess substitutability in local advertising among all sources
                of video in a DMA. The Commission seeks comment and new data about
                whether and how various video programming providers compete for local
                advertising revenue.
                 30. Given the Commission's prior findings in the 2010/2014 Biennial
                Review Order that competition within local markets can produce better
                [[Page 6747]]
                programming and programming tailored to local needs and interests from
                which viewers benefit, the Commission seeks comment on whether, in
                evaluating the Local Television Ownership Rule, it should consider
                sources of local news and other local programming as a relevant product
                market. What are the most prominent sources of local news and local
                programming beyond broadcast television? Should non-video providers of
                news and information--such as radio, newspapers, internet websites, and
                social media platforms--be examined in the product market analysis? To
                what extent do potential viewers rely for local news on these
                alternative sources? Given Knight Foundation reports that online-only
                local news websites have limited impact, are these sources originators
                of local programming, or do they simply aggregate or utilize content
                generated by traditional local news sources? Are non-broadcast sources
                of local programming available in all DMAs or are they just in major
                markets? Is the depth of any coverage of local issues by non-broadcast
                platforms consistent across DMAs? The Commission seeks comment on the
                availability and variety of local video programming in each Nielsen DMA
                and on how the Commission would, and if it should, evaluate local
                programming for purposes of any programming-based analysis. The
                Commission seeks comment on whether defining the local product market
                for our television ownership rules to include specific types of
                programming would raise First Amendment concerns.
                 31. What measures could the Commission use to assess competition
                among sources of local video programming or other local content? What
                data sources might the Commission use to determine which sources
                consumers consider substitutes? Given the lack of a single, accepted,
                industry-wide standard for measuring online viewership, how should the
                Commission account for various providers of news, information, and
                video programming to the extent that some entities, such as OVDs and
                websites, may lack an industry standard for measuring viewership and
                engagement?
                 32. The Commission also seeks comment on the relationship between
                its local television ownership market definition and any changes
                thereto, and the market definition and analysis used by DOJ, which
                examines local television broadcasters competing in the spot
                advertising market. The Commission stated in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial
                Review Order that its market definition when evaluating broadcast
                television mergers is like DOJ's in that the scope of the Commission's
                rule is similarly limited to local television broadcast stations. DOJ's
                analysis, however, has historically focused on competition for
                advertising, whereas the Commission's analysis focuses on multiple
                factors, including audience share. Recently in evaluating the
                combination of Nexstar and Media General, DOJ also looked at
                competition for retransmission consent licensing fees in local
                television markets. The Commission seeks comment on whether and how
                DOJ's analytical framework should inform its own, and vice versa. Are
                there ways in which the Commission's current rule is either consistent
                or inconsistent with antitrust principles? Do other public interest
                considerations support the rule?
                 33. Numerical Limit. Currently, a broadcast licensee can own up to
                two television stations (a duopoly) in a DMA, subject to the
                requirements of the Local Television Ownership Rule. In the 2010/2014
                Quadrennial Review Order, the Commission concluded that changes in the
                local television market demonstrated by the record were insufficient to
                justify either tightening or loosening this numerical limit. The
                Commission therefore seeks comment on whether subsequent changes in the
                video programming industry now support changes to the numerical limit.
                If the Commission finds that retaining a local television rule remains
                in the public interest, should it change the numerical limit on how
                many stations may be owned in a DMA?
                 34. Top-Four Prohibition. The Commission found in the 2010/2014
                Quadrennial Review Order that ratings data supported the Local
                Television Ownership Rule's focus on the top-four rated full power
                television stations in a market, that there typically remained a
                significant ``cushion'' of audience share points that separated the
                top-four stations in a market from the fifth-ranked station and below,
                and that the record supported potential harms associated with top-four
                combinations. The Commission seeks comment on the applicability of
                these previous conclusions based on new, updated ratings data and/or
                examples of existing commonly owned top-four station combinations. If
                the Commission retains a local television ownership rule, should the
                top four prohibition be retained or modified?
                 35. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration,
                the Commission recognized that rigid application of the Top-Four
                Prohibition in all DMAs may not be supported by the unique conditions
                present in certain DMAs or with respect to certain transactions, and
                accordingly adopted a hybrid approach to allow applicants to seek a
                case-by-case examination of a proposed combination that would otherwise
                be prohibited by the Top-Four Prohibition. The Commission stated that
                the types of information applicants could provide on competition in the
                local market in such examinations included: (1) Ratings share data of
                the stations proposed to be combined compared with other stations in
                the market; (2) revenue share data of the stations proposed to be
                combined compared with other stations in the market, including
                advertising (on-air and digital) and retransmission consent fees; (3)
                market characteristics, such as population and the number and types of
                broadcast television stations serving the market (including any strong
                competitors outside the top-four rated broadcast television stations);
                (4) the likely effects on programming meeting the needs and interests
                of the community; and (5) any other circumstances impacting the market,
                particularly any disparities primarily impacting small and mid-sized
                markets.
                 36. The Commission asks whether flexibility in applying the Top-
                Four prohibition remains necessary and, if so, whether the case-by-case
                approach is the most effective way to achieve it. If the Commission
                finds that a case-by-case analysis is the best approach, do the types
                of information listed in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on
                Reconsideration serve as reliable factors in determining whether a top-
                four combination would serve the public interest? If so, should some
                factors be weighed more heavily than others in the analysis? Are there
                factors in addition to the examples provided in the 2010/2014
                Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration that the Commission should
                consider? What kinds of data should licensees provide to support their
                showings? Should the Commission adopt a more rigid set of criteria for
                its case-by-case determination?
                 37. Alternatively, should the Commission avoid a case-by-case or
                hybrid approach and establish a bright-line test that would permit
                common ownership of two top-four stations in all cases, or in
                particular markets or circumstances? For example, should the Commission
                permit common ownership of the fourth-ranked station in a market and
                either the second-ranked station or third-ranked station in that same
                market? Should the Commission allow combinations between the second-
                ranked station or third-ranked station in the same market? Should such
                combinations only be permitted in
                [[Page 6748]]
                smaller markets where there is less advertising revenue available to
                support programming and station operations? The Commission also seeks
                comment on whether it should create a presumption for permitting common
                ownership of two top-four stations if certain conditions are met. What
                conditions should the Commission consider in determining if a
                combination would not negatively impact competition? For example,
                should the Commission presume that a combination is permissible if the
                combined stations' share of the audience and/or advertising market
                share does not exceed a certain threshold?
                 38. If the Commission either retains the case-by-case approach or
                adopts a bright-line test, it seeks comment on how to analyze
                competition in local television markets. In considering the effect of
                top-four combinations on local advertising markets, the Commission
                seeks studies that estimate the elasticity of demand for local
                advertising. In the absence of such studies, what data sources or types
                of data might the Commission use to assess substitutability in local
                advertising across dayparts, program types, and stations? What
                measures, in addition to viewership share, could be used to assess
                competition between stations in local programming? What data sources
                might we use to determine which programs or stations viewers consider
                substitutes?
                 39. A top-four combination may have different effects on
                competition among broadcast stations for viewers of different types of
                programming, for instance, local programming, network programming, and
                syndicated programming. Should the Commission weigh each competitive
                effect and, if so, how? If the Commission considers specific categories
                of programming, should it look at the viewership of each type of
                programming, the amount of revenue generated for the local station by
                each type of programming, both, or something else? Top-four
                combinations may also affect the quantity or quality of local
                programming available in the market. Although intended primarily to
                promote competition, does the Top-Four Prohibition also preserve, as a
                byproduct, a sufficient level of localism or viewpoint diversity in
                local markets? The Commission seeks comment on whether and how it
                should consider elimination of an independent local news operation or a
                reduction in local news programming.
                 40. The Commission also seeks comment on whether and how it should
                weigh any effect on retransmission consent negotiations in evaluating
                competitive effects under the Commission's case-by-case approach to
                evaluating top-four station combinations. Commenters in proceedings
                involving potential top-four station combinations consistently have
                raised the issue of potential retransmission consent fee increases
                because of reduced competition between stations and undue bargaining
                leverage for stations if commonly owned top-four stations are able to
                negotiate such fees jointly as a result of the combination. In its
                Nexstar-Media General review, DOJ also recognized that common ownership
                of two major broadcast network affiliates can lead to diminished
                competition in the negotiation of retransmission agreements with MVPDs
                in local television markets. The Commission therefore seeks comment on
                whether and how it should weigh the effect on retransmission consent
                negotiations in evaluating top-four station combinations under its
                case-by-case approach. Should the Commission maintain the Top-Four
                Prohibition for purposes of preventing any potential competitive harms
                caused by joint negotiation of retransmission consent fees by two
                commonly owned top-four stations in a DMA, and would such an approach
                be inconsistent with congressional intent in prohibiting joint
                negotiation only when conducted by non-commonly owned stations in the
                STELA Reauthorization Act of 2014?
                 41. If the Commission keeps the Top-Four Prohibition or a similar
                rule that relies on the ranking of stations by audience share or
                viewership, should any specific provisions of the rule be modified? The
                rule currently determines a station's in-market ranking based on the
                most recent all-day (9 a.m.-midnight) audience share, as measured by
                Nielsen Media Research. The Commission seeks comment on whether this
                data point is still the most useful for accurately determining a
                station's ranking for purposes of the Top-Four Prohibition. Have there
                been changes in the industry that necessitate examining different data?
                The Commission also seeks comment on whether and how it should account
                for instances where a station makes use of multicast streams, satellite
                stations, or translators. Should the ratings of these stations or
                streams be combined with the ratings of the primary station or stream
                to determine the station's ratings in the DMA? Why or why not? Lastly,
                based on Commission staff review of Nielsen data, there are instances
                where noncommercial television stations have audience shares comparable
                to those of commercial stations. Should the Commission distinguish
                between commercial and noncommercial stations for purposes of the Top-
                Four Prohibition? Why or why not?
                 42. The Commission seeks comment on whether to provide
                clarification of the phrase ``at the time the application to acquire or
                construct the station(s) is filed.'' Should entities filing an
                application submit as support audience share data for the most recent
                month, week, or sweeps period in relation to the date when the
                application was submitted to the Commission? Should the time frame for
                the submitted data be required to show a longer period? For example,
                should the Commission require applicants to submit ratings data over a
                three-year period to demonstrate that a station truly is or is not
                ranked among the top-four stations in the DMA ``at the time the
                application to acquire or construct the station(s) is filed'' as
                suggested in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order on Reconsideration?
                If not, should the Commission take another approach to prevent
                circumvention of the Top-Four Prohibition's requirements based on
                anomalous data? Should it rely on the most recent period solely as a
                presumption, which might be rebutted by interested parties?
                 43. Given the longstanding nature of the Top-Four Prohibition, much
                of the discussion in this section focuses on the continued
                applicability of that rule and ways that it might be adjusted or
                clarified to apply in the current video marketplace. The Commission
                also seeks comment on alternatives to the Top-Four Prohibition. Should
                common ownership of two stations in a market be permitted when at least
                one of the stations is not ranked among the top-three stations in the
                market, or among the top-two? What economic data support establishing
                such a top-three approach, considering the significant differences in
                national audience share between the top-four national networks and
                others? Should the Commission distinguish between stations located in
                larger Nielsen DMAs and those in mid- to small-sized DMAs by adopting a
                tiered approach to application of any ranking-based prohibition? Should
                common ownership be permitted when there is a certain number of non-
                broadcast local video programing sources in a DMA? The Commission seeks
                comment on how these and any other proposals supported by the record
                would promote and protect competition in local television markets.
                 44. Multicasting. As a result of the digital television transition,
                all full-power television stations have the ability to use their
                available spectrum to
                [[Page 6749]]
                broadcast not only their main program stream but also, if they choose,
                additional program streams--an activity commonly referred to as
                multicasting. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order the Commission
                distinguished between the ability to multicast and ownership of a
                separate broadcast station and declined to impose restrictions on local
                television station ownership based on the ability to multicast. Because
                the record indicated that dual affiliations involving two Big Four
                networks (ABC, CBS, Fox, and NBC) via multicasting were generally
                limited to smaller markets where there was an insufficient number of
                full-power commercial television stations to accommodate each Big Four
                network or where other unique marketplace factors led to creating the
                dual affiliation, the Commission declined to regulate dual affiliations
                through multicasting, even in instances where a licensee is affiliated
                with more than one of the Big Four networks. The Commission stated,
                however, that it would continue to monitor this issue and act in the
                future, if appropriate.
                 45. The Commission now seeks comment on how technical and other
                developments in the broadcast industry have affected multicasting. Are
                some multicast streams functioning as the equivalent of separate
                broadcast stations? Multicasting has enabled broadcasters to bring more
                programming to consumers, particularly in smaller, rural markets, by
                expanding the availability of the four major networks and newer
                networks. Based on Commission staff review of Nielsen data, there are
                at least several dozen DMAs where a single entity holds affiliations
                with two Big Four networks by using a multicast stream to carry the
                second signal. Thus, the Commission seeks comment on the
                characteristics of DMAs where major network affiliations are carried on
                multicast streams. Are there certain markets where this practice is
                more commonplace? Do dual affiliations with major networks remains
                limited to smaller markets or has the practice become more widespread?
                The Commission asks whether and how it should evaluate multicast
                streams for purposes of the Local Television Ownership Rule.
                 46. Satellite Stations. Television satellite stations are full-
                power broadcast stations authorized under Part 73 of the Commission's
                rules that generally retransmit some or all of the programming of
                another television station, known as the parent station, which
                typically is commonly owned or operated with the satellite station.
                Satellite stations are exempt from the Local Television Ownership Rule,
                and the Commission seeks comment on their use to carry two Big Four
                networks in a market. For instance, how should the Commission treat a
                situation in which a licensee utilizes multicasting to air two Big Four
                networks on a parent station (e.g., one on the primary stream and one
                on a multicast stream), and airs the same two Big Four networks on a
                satellite station? How prevalent is this practice, and is it consistent
                with the purposes behind allowing satellite stations in the first
                place, which are generally intended to bring over-the-air television
                service to unserved areas? Are there benefits to allowing this practice
                that outweigh any potential harms? The Commission seeks comment on
                whether this issue should be addressed through modification of the
                satellite exemption to the Local Television Ownership Rule or,
                alternatively, in the context of the satellite authorization process.
                 47. Low Power Television Stations. Changes in industry practice and
                technological advances may have extended the reach and enhanced the
                capabilities of low power and translator television broadcast stations
                that are currently exempt from local television ownership limits. Based
                on a review of Nielsen data by Commission staff, there are a
                significant number of low power stations affiliated with a Big Four
                network. Because of this affiliation, MVPDs are likely willing to carry
                the low power stations, which qualify for must-carry on cable systems
                under very limited circumstances, despite their status. If low power
                stations can in this way become the functional equivalent of full power
                stations in certain instances, should the Commission account for the
                number of low power television stations as part of its Local Television
                Ownership Rule in some way, and if so, how? For instance, should a low
                power station that is ranked among the top four stations in audience
                share in a DMA be counted as a top-four station for purposes of the
                Top-Four Prohibition?
                 48. Next Generation Broadcast Television Transmission Standard.
                Currently, the broadcast television industry is developing a new
                transmission standard called Advanced Television Systems Committee
                (ATSC) 3.0 with the intent of merging the capabilities of over-the-air
                broadcasting with the broadband viewing and information delivery
                methods of the internet, using the same 6 MHz channels presently
                allocated for DTV service. According to ATSC 3.0 advocates, the new
                standard has the potential to improve broadcast signal reception
                greatly, particularly on mobile devices and television receivers
                without outdoor antennas. ATSC 3.0 will enable broadcasters to offer
                enhanced and innovative new features to consumers, including Ultra High
                Definition (UHD) picture and immersive audio, more localized
                programming content, an advanced emergency alert system (EAS) capable
                of waking up sleeping devices to warn consumers of imminent
                emergencies, better accessibility options, and interactive services.
                 49. The Commission seeks comment on the implications, if any, of
                the new broadcast television transmission standard on the Local
                Television Ownership Rule. The Commission also seeks comment on whether
                any provisions of the Local Television Ownership Rule potentially could
                affect adoption and deployment of the new transmission standard. How,
                if at all, should the Commission in the context of local television
                ownership consider the decisions of television broadcasters to adopt
                voluntarily the ATSC 3.0 transmission standard?
                 50. Broadcast Spectrum Auction. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
                Order, the Commission stated that it could not yet determine how the
                incentive auction would affect the Local Television Ownership Rule. On
                April 13, 2017, the Commission released a public notice announcing the
                results of the reverse and forward auctions and the repacking of the
                broadcast television spectrum. Pursuant to the statute authorizing the
                incentive auction, that public notice marked the auction's completion
                and the start of the 39-month post-auction transition period. Given
                completion of the auction and the subsequent surrender of spectrum and/
                or initiation of channel-sharing agreements, the Commission seeks
                comment on whether the auction's effects on local television ownership
                have any implication on retention or modification of the Local
                Television Ownership Rule.
                 51. Shared Service Agreements. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
                Order, the Commission adopted a definition of shared service agreements
                (SSAs) and, despite opposition from broadcasters, a requirement that
                commercial television stations disclose SSAs by placing them in their
                online public inspection files. The Commission also found it lacked
                knowledge about the content, scope, and prevalence of SSAs that kept it
                from evaluating the impact of these agreements, if any, on its policy
                goals with respect to broadcast ownership. The 2010/2014 Quadrennial
                Review Order on Reconsideration upheld the disclosure requirement,
                which took effect on March 23, 2018. The Commission now seeks comment
                on
                [[Page 6750]]
                what action, if any, it should take on SSAs in the context of this 2018
                review of the Local Television Ownership Rule. Should the Commission
                retain or eliminate the SSA filing requirement? What, if anything, have
                commenters learned from filing the agreements so far?
                 52. Minority and Female Ownership. The Commission stated in the
                2010/2014 Quadrennial Order that, while the Local Television Ownership
                Rule promotes competition among broadcast television stations in local
                markets and is not meant to preserve or create specific amounts of
                minority and female ownership, the rule nevertheless promotes
                opportunities for diversity in local television ownership. The
                Commission concluded that the competition-based rule helps to ensure
                the presence of independently owned broadcast television stations in
                the local market, thereby indirectly increasing the likelihood of a
                variety of viewpoints and preserving ownership opportunities for new
                entrants. The record held no data indicating that the duopoly rule has
                reduced minority ownership or suggested that a return to the single
                station per licensee rule would increase ownership opportunities for
                minorities and women. While the data did indicate an increase in
                minority ownership following relaxation of the Local Television
                Ownership Rule, there was no evidence in the record that established a
                causal connection. The Commission now asks how retaining, modifying, or
                eliminating the local television rule would affect broadcast television
                ownership and entry by minority and female owners, if at all. The
                Commission seeks data and an updated record on the effects of the Local
                Television Ownership Rule on minority and female broadcast ownership
                and entry. Finally, the Commission seeks comment on how retaining or
                modifying the rule might affect broadcast television ownership and
                entry by small business owners, if at all.
                 53. Dual Network Rule. The Dual Network Rule permits common
                ownership of multiple broadcast networks, but effectively prohibits a
                merger between or among the Big Four networks. In the 2010/2014
                Quadrennial Review Order, the Commission concluded that the Dual
                Network Rule continues to be necessary in the public interest to
                promote competition and localism. With respect to competition, the
                Commission found the rule necessary to promote both competition in the
                provision of primetime entertainment programming and the sale of
                national advertising. With respect to localism, the Commission found
                that the rule was necessary to preserve the balance of power between
                the Big Four networks and their local affiliates.
                 54. In conducting its analysis of whether the Dual Network Rule
                remains necessary, the Commission traditionally has considered
                broadcast networks as participating in the video marketplace in two
                ways: (1) Assembling and distributing a collection of programming
                suitable for large, national audiences, and (2) selling advertising
                based on this programming to large, national advertisers. Does the Dual
                Network Rule continue to be relevant to competition or network behavior
                in either or both of these segments? The Commission concluded in the
                2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order that ``the primetime entertainment
                programming provided by the Big Four broadcast networks and national
                television advertising time are each a distinct product--the
                availability, price, and quality of which could be restricted, to the
                detriment of consumers, if two [Big Four broadcast networks] were
                permitted to merge.'' Does this conclusion remain valid? The Commission
                also generally seeks comment on whether the Dual Network Rule remains
                necessary to promote its goals of competition, viewpoint diversity and
                localism, and on whether the benefits of the rule outweigh any costs.
                 55. Regarding viewership, in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order
                the Commission found, based on Nielsen data, that no cable programming
                could deliver primetime audiences on par with, let alone greater than,
                the primetime audiences delivered by the Big Four networks. The
                Commission's Eighteenth Video Competition Report, based on 2015 data,
                showed that broadcast affiliates still draw the largest share of total
                day and prime time viewing audiences in relation to independent
                stations and non-commercial and cable networks. The 2010/2014
                Quadrennial Review Order also found a continued wide disparity in the
                advertising rates and revenue earned by the Big Four networks and other
                broadcast and cable networks. The Commission seeks more current data on
                these topics. Do these or other recent developments have any
                implications for the Commission's competition rationale underlying the
                Dual Network Rule?
                 56. The Commission also found in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review
                Order and in previous reviews of the Dual Network Rule that the Big
                Four networks operate as a ``strategic group'' in the national
                advertising market and that they largely compete among themselves for
                the most significant portion of the national advertising market, namely
                advertisers that seek to reach national mass audiences. The Commission
                further found that the programming provided by the Big Four networks
                was a distinct product that, when compared to other broadcast and cable
                programming, had a unique ability to regularly attract large prime-time
                audiences and thus command higher advertising rates. Does the
                Commission's ``strategic group'' finding still hold true? Given the
                increasing number of video programmers in today's market, as well as
                the increasing popularity of their programming, is network broadcast
                programming still a distinct product? Does nightly network news
                programming, or any other programming, distinguish the broadcast
                networks, or are consumers now turning to other news or programming
                sources that remove this distinction? Are there other producers of mass
                audience programming such that a merger between two of the Big Four
                networks would no longer harm competition for national advertising? In
                the past, the Commission reviewed programming audience shares and the
                advertising rates and revenues of various programmers in making this
                determination. Should the Commission continue to rely on these data, or
                are there other data or metrics it should consider? Are there better
                sources of relevant data than the Commission has considered in the
                past?
                 57. One of the biggest changes in the video programming market has
                been online distribution of programming from a variety of sources.
                Today, OVDs--including linear multichannel streaming services, both
                those from social media companies and other online platforms, and
                direct-to-consumer offerings by broadcast networks themselves--reach
                millions of consumers. Digital advertising on these or other online
                platforms is steadily increasing in market and revenue share. How, if
                at all, have these changes affected competition for national broadcast
                television advertising? The Commission seeks comment on whether and how
                any such changes should affect our Dual Network Rule.
                 58. The Commission also seeks comment on whether recent
                developments in the video programming and national advertising markets
                suggest that the Dual Network Rule should be modified to promote
                competition or eliminated. If the rule is modified, what changes should
                we make? Should networks be removed from or added to the rule? If so,
                which networks? What would be the basis for eliminating the
                [[Page 6751]]
                rule? If the rule were eliminated, would antitrust statutes or any
                other statutes, rules, or policies serve as a sufficient backstop to
                prevent undue consolidation between or among the Big Four networks? Why
                or why not?
                 59. The Commission also seeks comment on whether The Dual Network
                Rule remains necessary to promote localism, in particular by
                maintaining a balance of power between the Big Four networks and their
                local affiliates. To reach the largest possible national audience, the
                Big Four networks acquire their own broadcast stations, usually in the
                largest television markets, and enter into affiliation agreements with
                station owners throughout the rest of the country. Through affiliation,
                a model which has existed for more than fifty years, networks benefit
                through wide delivery of their programming, and network affiliates
                benefit by gaining access to high-quality programming. The Commission
                has found in previous media ownership rule reviews that the network-
                affiliate model balances competing interests: Networks have an economic
                incentive to ensure that programming appeals to a mass, nationwide
                audience while affiliates have an economic incentive to tailor
                programming to their local audiences and influence network programming
                choices to ensure that the programming serves local needs and
                interests. Affiliates also may decide individually to preempt network
                programming for other programming better serving the local audience.
                The Commission now seeks comment on whether these specific conclusions,
                and the Commission's general conclusion that the Dual Network Rule is
                needed to keep the balance of bargaining power between the Big Four
                networks and their affiliates, remain true in today's video
                marketplace.
                 60. Evidence submitted in the Commission's review of the Comcast-
                NBCU merger suggested that broadcast network affiliation remains sought
                after and critical to many local stations' success. Also, while
                advertising revenue remains essential to broadcast stations, the
                Eighteenth Video Competition Report showed that retransmission consent
                revenues now represent a much greater proportion of total revenue for
                many broadcast stations than previously, and stations with Big Four
                network affiliations often receive the lion's share of retransmission
                consent dollars from MVPDs in a local market. The Eighteenth Video
                Competition Report also showed that, whereas local affiliates were once
                paid by networks to distribute network programming, today networks seek
                and receive compensation from their affiliates in the form of reverse
                compensation payments. According to one estimate by SNL Kagan, total
                industrywide reverse compensation payments paid by affiliates to
                broadcast networks have increased from roughly $300 million in 2010 to
                $2.9 billion in 2017. There is some evidence too that networks now
                exert leverage through oversight or approval of affiliate
                retransmission consent negotiations, and although not common, in some
                instances in recent years a network dropped or threatened to drop a
                local affiliate to launch a network O&O station in the same market. To
                what extent do networks extract a share of retransmission consent
                payments received by their affiliates? How, if at all, should the Dual
                Network Rule account for these or other recent changes to the network/
                affiliate relationship?
                 61. In addition, the rise of online video options in recent years
                also may have altered the network-affiliate dynamic. As stated above,
                OVDs now reach millions of consumers, creating new opportunities for
                networks to achieve widespread distribution without the direct
                involvement of network affiliates. In the broadcast-MVPD world of
                retransmission consent, local affiliates may have some recourse against
                broadcast networks bypassing their affiliates in this manner by
                negotiating for, and if necessary enforcing via Commission rules,
                contractual network non-duplication rights, which protect a broadcast
                station's right to be the exclusive distributor of network programming
                within a specified geographic zone. By contrast, in the world of online
                video distribution, local affiliates lack a comparable regulatory
                backstop. The ability of networks to achieve online distribution of
                network programming in a local market, without the need for local
                affiliates to consent, may give networks some additional leverage in
                the network-affiliate relationship that did not exist in the pre-online
                video world. What implications, if any, do developments related to the
                growth of online video distribution have for the Dual Network Rule and
                its underlying localism rationale?
                 62. As the Commission has previously noted, the Dual Network Rule
                is intended to preserve the ability of local affiliates to advocate for
                local interests in programming decisions. Would a Big Four network
                merger reduce the ability of a network affiliate to use the
                availability of other top, independently-owned networks as a bargaining
                tool to influence programming decisions of its network, including the
                affiliate's ability to engage in a dialogue with its network over the
                suitability for local audiences of either the content or scheduling of
                network programming? Have changes discussed above, including the growth
                of online video or increased reverse compensation and retransmission
                consent fees, affected bargaining between networks and affiliates on
                programming and scheduling?
                 63. Considering the longstanding existence of the Dual Network
                Rule, has localism increased, decreased, or remained roughly the same
                over time? Are there recent examples where local affiliates have
                influenced network programming to better serve local needs? Are there
                other metrics by which we can assess the effect of the Dual Network
                Rule on localism? Have other changes affected the network/affiliate
                relationship, such that the Commission would need to adjust assumptions
                made in previous reviews of the Dual Network Rule? For instance, has
                the growth over the last two decades of station groups not owned and
                operated by networks changed the dynamic between networks and their
                affiliates? Do recent changes affecting the network-affiliate
                relationship suggest that the Dual Network Rule should be modified,
                rather than being retained or eliminated, to promote localism? If so,
                what modifications should we make that would better promote localism?
                 64. Minority and Female Ownership. The Commission concluded in the
                2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order that, given the Dual Network Rule's
                unique focus on mergers involving the Big Four networks rather than
                ownership limits in local markets, the rule would not be expected to
                have any meaningful impact on minority and female ownership levels. The
                Commission seeks comment on whether and how market or other changes
                since its last media ownership review may have affected this
                conclusion. The Commission also seeks comment on how retaining,
                modifying or eliminating the Dual Network Rule would affect broadcast
                television ownership and entry by minority and female owners, if at
                all. Finally, the Commission seeks comment on how retaining or
                modifying the Dual Network Rule might affect broadcast television
                ownership and entry by small business owners, if at all.
                 65. Diversity Related Proposals. The NPRM also seeks comment on
                three proposals for increasing media diversity advanced by MMTC in
                prior proceedings. These three proposals were distilled from a larger
                list based on guidance from the Third Circuit in its decisions and
                Commission staff, and the Commission already has adopted two
                [[Page 6752]]
                additional proposals from this list. The three proposals the Commission
                now considers are: (1) Extending cable procurement requirements to
                broadcasters; (2) developing a model for market based tradable
                ``diversity credits'' to serve as an alternative method for adopting
                ownership limits; and (3) adopting formulas aimed at creating media
                ownership limits that promote diversity.
                 66. Extending Cable Procurement Regulation. The 1992 Cable Act
                states that a cable system must: ``[e]ncourage minority and female
                entrepreneurs to conduct business with all parts of its operation.''
                Sec. 76.75(e) of the Commission's rules explains that this requirement
                may be met by, for example, recruiting as wide as possible a pool of
                qualified entrepreneurs from sources such as employee referrals,
                community groups, contractors, associations, and other sources likely
                to be representative of minority and female interests. To help
                determine whether this requirement can be applied to broadcasters, the
                Commission seeks comment on the threshold issue of whether, because
                Commission cable procurement authority flows directly from the 1992
                Cable Act, it has authority to adopt a procurement requirement for
                broadcasters. The Communications Act imposes equal employment
                opportunity obligations on broadcasters, but no procurement
                requirements. Does this difference between the two statutes reflect any
                limitation on the Commission's otherwise extensive Communications Act
                Title III authority over broadcasters? The Commission seeks comment on
                potential sources of Commission authority, including any ancillary
                authority, to extend procurement regulations to the broadcast industry.
                The Commission also seeks comment on whether, by specifically
                identifying minority/female entrepreneurs, the proposal would classify
                these entrepreneurs differently from others such as to trigger
                heightened judicial scrutiny. If heightened scrutiny is triggered, how
                would such a rule comport with the Commission's previous finding in the
                2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order that it lacked the evidence to
                satisfy the heightened scrutiny needed to justify race- or gender-based
                broadcast regulation? Would inclusion of any type of audit, review, or
                enforcement mechanism pursuant to which the Commission considered
                broadcasters' compliance with the requirement be problematic or
                interpreted as tacitly encouraging broadcasters to favor certain
                entrepreneurs to the detriment of others in a way that would trigger
                heightened scrutiny?
                 67. If a broadcast procurement rule as proposed by MMTC would
                trigger heightened judicial scrutiny, can any proposed rule be modified
                to be race- and gender-neutral to avoid the potential legal impediments
                raised by a race- and gender-conscious broadcast procurement rule? In
                such a case, how would the requirement be stated? Would a race- and
                gender-neutral broadcast procurement rule be as effective as a race-
                and gender-conscious broadcast procurement rule?
                 68. The Commission also seeks comment on MMTC's assertion in the
                2010/2014 Quadrennial Review that Sec. 76.75(e) ``has been a
                springboard for the migration of minority and women entrepreneurs into
                operating and ownership positions in the cable and satellite
                industries[,]'' and has ``contributed mightily to the economic success
                of scores of minority and women owned businesses engaged in banking,
                broker/dealer services, construction, fiber and satellite dish
                installation, programming, legal services, accounting, and much more.''
                In deciding whether to adopt additional regulations or extend a
                regulation to additional industries, it is important to assess the
                likelihood that the regulation would have the desired effect of
                increasing minority and female participation in the broadcast industry.
                Consequently, the Commission seeks data on the degree to which Sec.
                76.75(e) has promoted minority and women businesses and whether any
                broader trends in the intervening two decades since enactment of the
                cable procurement requirement have played a role in fostering greater
                minority and female participation in the cable industry. In this
                regard, we also seek comment on the relative benefits and costs of
                extending Sec. 76.75(e) to the broadcast industry. How can the value
                of these benefits and costs be measured?
                 69. The Commission also notes the significant differences between
                the cable and broadcast industries and seeks comment on the
                feasibility--and utility--of imposing a Sec. 76.75(e)-type requirement
                on the broadcast industry. For example, unlike broadcasters, cable
                providers must construct and continuously maintain and upgrade a
                significant physical plant and therefore purchase goods and services on
                a much larger scale than broadcasters. Over-the-air delivery of
                broadcast radio and television does not require laying fiber or coaxial
                cable to every home and, in most instances, deploying customer premise
                equipment, necessitating regular purchase of equipment and material at
                significant volume. Constructing and maintaining extensive cable
                networks also requires employing and contracting for far more labor
                than is required in the broadcast sector. Unlike broadcasters, cable
                operators maintain a direct billing relationship with their customers,
                offering more contracting opportunities--in the form of outsourced
                billing or customer service functions--than the broadcast industry.
                Accordingly, the Commission seeks input on the feasibility and utility
                of imposing a cable procurement regulation on broadcasters.
                 70. Develop a Model for Market-Based Tradeable Diversity Credits.
                In reply comments submitted in the 2002 Biennial Review, a group called
                the Diversity and Competition Supporters (DCS) advanced several
                initiatives that it asserted would foster diversity, including
                tradeable ``diversity credits'' for the broadcast industry. While
                diversity credits weren't well defined, the idea appears to involve
                creating a system of credits tradable in a market-based system and
                redeemable by a broadcaster buying additional stations to offset any
                increased concentration resulting from a proposed transaction. DCS
                offered diversity credits as a potential alternative to the test then
                in use by the Commission requiring that, for a broadcaster to own two
                stations in a market, eight independent voices must have remained in
                the market post-transaction. DCS suggested that economists (presumably
                both at the Commission and beyond) could explore the concept and stated
                its hope ``that other parties will attempt to design a market-based
                Diversity Credit program.'' In 2004, a member of the Transactional
                Transparency Subcommittee of the FCC Advisory Committee on Diversity in
                the Digital Age further developed the diversity credits concept,
                suggesting credits linked to each broadcast license based on the extent
                to which the licensee was ``socially and economically disadvantaged''
                and that, if a transaction promoted diversity (e.g., the breakup of a
                local ownership cluster or the sale of a station to a socially and
                economically disadvantaged business), the Commission would award the
                seller additional diversity credits ``commensurate with the extent to
                which the transaction promotes diversity.'' Similarly, according to
                this 2004 proposal, if a transaction reduced diversity (e.g., by
                creating an ownership combination or growing an ownership cluster), the
                Commission would require diversity credits from the buyer, commensurate
                with the extent to the which the transaction reduced diversity.
                [[Page 6753]]
                Finally, according to the 2004 proposal, if a company seeking approval
                of a transaction held insufficient diversity credits to gain approval,
                the company would need to purchase diversity credits on a secondary
                market from third-party companies. The proposal did not define either
                ``promoting'' or ``reducing'' diversity, or how the impact of a
                transaction would be measured or quantified. MMTC continued to advocate
                for tradable diversity credits in the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review,
                asking the Commission to explore their feasibility by issuing a Notice
                of Inquiry. Therefore, the Commission now seeks comment on whether and
                how it should create a system of tradable diversity credits that would
                foster ownership diversity in broadcasting.
                 71. The Commission first seeks comment on its authority to adopt a
                tradeable diversity credit system within its structural broadcast
                ownership rules or otherwise. While the Communications Act contains no
                explicit authority to create or rely on such a program, when presenting
                the idea, DCS asserted that the sections 303(f), (g), and (r) of the
                Communications Act provided authority to implement tradable diversity
                credits. Are the sections cited by DCS applicable to such credits?
                 72. Assuming it has the required authority, the Commission seeks
                comment on the feasibility of relying on determinations about social
                and economic disadvantage given its concerns, expressed in the 2010/
                2014 Quadrennial Review Order, about relying on such determinations. As
                proposed, the allocation of diversity credits was based on the extent
                to which the licensee could be considered ``socially and economically
                disadvantaged.'' How should the term ``socially and economically
                disadvantaged'' business (SDB) be defined? The 2004 proposal stated
                that, ``[m]inority status could be a factor in qualifying as an SDB if
                the Commission finds through rulemaking that minorities, under certain
                conditions, are socially and economically disadvantaged in the
                broadcasting industry because of their race[,]'' but did not provide
                any guidance about when an individual might or might not qualify on the
                basis of race. In the 2010/2014 Quadrennial Review Order, the
                Commission found that the record did not establish a basis for race-
                conscious remedies and concluded that such measures were unlikely to
                withstand review under the equal protection component of the
                Constitution's due process clause. Thus, the Commission, unlike the
                Small Business Administration (SBA), declined to adopt an SDB
                eligibility standard that would have recognized the race and ethnicity
                of applicants, or any other race- or gender-conscious measure. Given
                the Commission's previous findings and conclusions, can it adopt a
                diversity credit program that considers race or gender, or other
                protected classes, in a manner that could withstand equal protection
                review? Commenters advocating for such a program should explain in
                detail, based on relevant judicial precedent and existing empirical
                data, how circumstances have changed such that the Commission could now
                overcome the significant evidentiary issues that it previously found
                would need to be resolved to adopt race- or gender-based policies that
                could withstand heightened judicial scrutiny.
                 73. If the socially and economically disadvantaged concept in the
                2004 proposal was a precursor to the Overcoming Disadvantages
                Preference (ODP) concept that MMTC has advanced in subsequent
                Commission rulemaking proceedings, the Commission in the 2010/2014
                Quadrennial Review FNPRM assessed the ODP concept and stated concerns
                that the Commission lacks the resources needed to conduct the
                individualized reviews central to ODP. The Commission has similar
                concerns about the administrative and practical challenges of
                developing, implementing and applying a diversity credits program. The
                2004 proposal suggested that the program rely on ascribing a diversity
                credits number to each broadcast license or possibly each licensee. Who
                would make that allocation of diversity credits, and on what criteria
                would the Commission or other arbiter determine the number of credits
                to be awarded to each license or licensee?
                 74. Such a program also raises potentially complicated definitional
                issues. How would the Commission define ``diversity'' in this context?
                In the 2002 Biennial Review Order, the Commission described several
                types of diversity, focusing on viewpoint diversity as the relevant
                touchstone for purposes of the structural media ownership rules. Would
                a diversity credit system have as its goal fostering viewpoint
                diversity, ownership diversity, both forms of diversity, or some other
                type of diversity?
                 75. Once diversity is defined, how would parties--or the
                Commission--determine, qualitatively or quantitatively, whether a
                transaction promotes or harms diversity? How would the degree to which
                the transaction harms or benefits diversity be quantified, such that
                the number of credits awarded for, or required before approval of, such
                a transaction could be determined? For example, would the impact on
                diversity vary depending on the size of the market, the number of
                operators therein, or the characteristics of the stations involved in
                the transaction? Would a requirement that parties remit to the
                Commission a certain number of diversity credits to receive approval of
                a transaction replace the Commission's existing structural broadcast
                ownership rules, which are based primarily on other policy goals, such
                as competition and localism? Or would compliance with the diversity
                credit regime be an additional requirement before a transaction were
                permitted?
                 76. Recognizing that diversity credits could be used as a form of
                currency in the broadcast market, how could the Commission effectively
                test such a scheme to ensure it would not lead to any unintended
                consequences? Developing and implementing a system that ensures that
                the award of diversity credits leads to the desired result--increasing
                diverse ownership in the broadcast market--rather than inadvertently
                skewing the market towards an unintended outcome, including greater
                concentration or loss of localism and viewpoint diversity, would seem
                to be a particular challenge. The Commission seeks comment on how to
                address these issues.
                 77. Tipping Point Formula and Source Diversity Formula. In 2002,
                MMTC proposed a ``tipping point formula'' for use in the local radio
                market in lieu of the Commission's now-abandoned practice of
                ``flagging'' radio transactions that, after initial analysis based on
                advertising revenue, approached a level of local concentration that
                raised public interest concerns about preserving diversity and
                competition. In 2003, DCS proposed a ``source diversity formula'' for
                use in the broader media market that seemed to be an attempt to
                quantify the benefit derived from increased viewpoint diversity. As
                with diversity credits, the Communications Act provides no explicit
                authority to adopt or apply these formulas, and the Commission seeks
                comment on possible sources of such statutory authority. Moreover,
                because MMTC and DCS have provided little update to the formulas since
                proposing them, the Commission seeks input generally on their relevance
                in today's marketplace. The formulas also raise administrative and
                practical concerns on which the Commission seeks comment, as discussed
                below.
                [[Page 6754]]
                 78. MMTC's tipping point formula attempted to determine when a
                proposed transaction would create an entity that could control so much
                advertising revenue that ``well run independents'' could not survive or
                offer ``meaningful local service'' (all undefined). The formula's
                asserted goal was to assess how much ``revenue'' an ``independent''
                would need on average to survive in a given market, with this number
                then being multiplied by the number of ``independents'' in that market.
                Because the Commission's abandoned flagging approach relied on
                advertising revenues, the term ``revenue'' in MMTC's tipping point
                formula appears also to refer to advertising revenue. MMTC essentially
                suggests that the Commission should bar any transaction that would
                reduce the revenue available to support independent operators in a
                market to an amount below what could sustain those operators. Stated
                differently, a broadcaster would not be permitted to acquire competing
                stations in a market if the purchase would create revenue so great as
                to leave insufficient revenue for the independents in the market. MMTC
                provided the following variables as inputs for its formula, as well as
                the formula shown below:
                 MR: Market revenue.
                 MR1: Amount of market revenue drawn by largest platform.
                 MR2: Amount of market revenue drawn by second largest platform.
                 IN: Number of independent stations in the market.
                 SU: Minimum fixed cost for an independent station to stay on the
                air.
                 VFSU: Variability Factor for Survival Operations, reflecting the
                average amount of revenues per independent station that must be
                available in the market, collectively, to take account of variations
                among the independent stations and thereby ensure that well-run weak
                independents stay on the air.
                 LS: Minimum additional cost, beyond SU, for an independent
                station to offer a meaningful local service.
                 VFLS: Variability Factor for Local Service reflecting the
                average amount of revenue per independent station that must be
                available in the market, collectively, to take account of variations
                among the independent stations and thereby ensure that well-run weak
                independents remain viable.
                 LSTP: Local Service Tipping Point, i.e., the point at which, if
                the top two station groups control more revenue, independents will
                begin to lose their ability to offer meaningful local service.
                 SUTP: Survival Tipping Point, i.e., the point at which, if the
                top two station groups control more revenue, independents will be
                unable to meet their fixed operating costs and must, therefore, sell
                out or go dark.
                Based on these inputs, according to MMTC, the Local Service Tipping
                Point is the point at which: IN (SU + VFSU + LS + VFLS) = MR-(MR1 +
                MR2), and the Survival Tipping point is the point at which: IN (SU +
                VFSU) = MR-(MR1 + MR2). In presenting these variables, MMTC noted that
                ``[t]he cost of maintaining a station on the air varies somewhat
                depending on local market factors[,]'' that such regional or local
                differences ``can be designed into a formula by indexing a market's
                cost of living relative to the national average[,]'' and that such
                issues could be addressed in a negotiated rulemaking involving all
                interested parties.
                 79. We seek comment on the various terms used in the formula. For
                example, how should the terms ``independent'' and ``platform'' be
                defined in the context of today's radio marketplace? How should the
                terms ``well-run independent'' and ``well-run weak independent'' be
                defined? What objective criteria can we apply to distinguish between a
                ``well-run independent'' and a ``well-run weak independent'' to ensure
                that use of a tipping point formula does not prop up stations that are
                either poorly managed or simply not airing programming that responds to
                the community's interests? What is meant by ``meaningful local
                service''? We also seek comment on whether any determinations about how
                well a station is run or the concept of ``meaningful local service''
                might create First Amendment concerns.
                 80. MMTC's formula appears to rely on advertising revenues. If so,
                how would the Commission and potential applicants obtain reliable
                advertising revenue for all radio stations? If another type of revenue
                is more appropriate, what data would the Commission rely on to obtain
                information about this other revenue? How should the concept of ``fixed
                operating costs'' be quantified? How should the Commission account for
                local and regional cost differences?
                 81. Finally, the Commission seeks comment on what seems to be the
                fundamental premise behind MMTC's tipping point formula: that retaining
                independents (however that term is defined) in a market maintains
                diversity (however that term is defined). We also invite commenters to
                address any other issues that they believe are raised by the tipping
                point formula proposal.
                 82. DCS submitted its source diversity formula in response to a
                challenge from then-Chairman Powell to derive an ``HHI [Herfindahl-
                Hirschman Index used to measure market concentration] for Diversity.''
                The formula appears to seek to measure the level of consumer welfare
                derived from viewpoint diversity in the radio and television broadcast
                market, and DCS suggested it could be a ``thermometer'' to determine
                whether ``a national or local market manifest[s] strong diversity,
                moderate diversity, or slight diversity.'' DCS proposed that the
                Commission conduct a negotiated rulemaking to determine what
                significance to accord to various ``temperature readings'' on this
                thermometer, i.e., what temperatures would reflect ``poor health,'' or
                ``strong health.'' DCS appeared to suggest that the source diversity
                formula could be used in lieu of the Commission's now-repealed ``eight
                voices'' test.
                 83. DCS depicted the source diversity formula as shown below with
                the following variables: X = consumer welfare derived from viewpoint
                diversity; p = a program consumed from a particular source; g = the
                number of programs from a particular source that are available for
                consumption; C = the number of consumers consuming a particular
                program; T = consumers' mean media consumption time devoted to the
                absorption of viewpoints in a particular program; Z = consumers' mean
                attentiveness to a particular program; m = a source (including all
                outlets owned by that source); and n = number of differently owned
                sources offering programs consumed. The formula as proposed was:
                [GRAPHIC] [TIFF OMITTED] TP28FE19.006
                DCS acknowledged that the formula was imperfect and would need testing
                and validation before deployment.
                 84. The formula raises several fundamental questions. Is the
                formula sufficiently comprehensive for commenters to gauge without
                additional explanation whether it can provide a meaningful assessment
                of consumer welfare and viewpoint diversity in a particular market? Are
                there terms used in the formula inputs that require definition prior to
                any assessment of the formula's utility? For example, do terms such as
                ``source'' and ``program'' need to
                [[Page 6755]]
                be defined before analyzing the formula? Are there other terms that
                need defining? How will the formula inputs be obtained? For example, we
                seek comment on how to capture inputs such as ``consumers' mean
                attentiveness to a particular program'' and ``consumers' mean media
                consumption time devoted to the absorption of viewpoints in a
                particular program.'' How should the Commission determine the level of
                diversity to ascribe to various formula results (e.g., ``strong
                diversity,'' ``moderate diversity,'' or ``slight diversity'')? Finally,
                the Commission invites commenters to address any other issues that they
                believe are raised by the source diversity formula.
                 85. Cost-Benefit Analysis. For the three structural media ownership
                rules and all of the diversity-related proposals discussed above, the
                Commission seeks comment on how to compare the benefits and costs
                associated with retaining, modifying or eliminating the rule or
                adopting the diversity-related proposal, with any proposed modification
                to the proposal. Commenters supporting modification or elimination of
                any rule or adoption of any proposal should explain the anticipated
                economic impact of any proposed action and, where possible, quantify
                benefits and costs of proposed actions and alternatives. Do the current
                rules create benefits or costs for any segment of consumers? Do the
                rules create benefits or costs for any segment of the industry that
                should be counted as social benefits or costs rather than transfers
                from one segment of the industry to another? How do the rules create
                these benefits and costs, and what evidence supports this explanation?
                How can the value of these benefits and costs be measured for parties
                receiving them? What factors create uncertainty about the existence or
                size of these benefits and costs, and how should the Commission's
                economic analysis take these uncertainties into account?
                 86. How would elimination of any rules alter the benefits and
                costs? What are the comparative benefits and costs of modifying any
                rule rather than eliminating it entirely? For instance, would loosening
                the current local television or local radio ownership restrictions, or
                allowing certain of the Big Four networks and not others to merge lead
                to any consumer benefits, such as increased choice, innovation, or
                investment in programming? What amount of additional scale would be
                required to realize such benefits? Would these benefits conflict with,
                or come at a cost to, our traditional policy goals of competition,
                viewpoint diversity or localism, and if so, how should we measure and
                evaluate these tradeoffs? What are the comparative benefits and costs
                of tightening the current restrictions? The Commission asks commenters
                to support their claims about benefits and costs with relevant economic
                theory and evidence, including empirical analysis and data.
                Procedural Matters
                 87. Ex Parte Rules--Permit-But-Disclose. The proceeding that this
                NPRM initiates shall be treated as a ``permit-but-disclose'' proceeding
                in accordance with the Commission's ex parte rules. Persons making ex
                parte presentations must file a copy of any written presentation or a
                memorandum summarizing any oral presentation within two business days
                after the presentation (unless a different deadline applicable to the
                Sunshine period applies). Persons making oral ex parte presentations
                are reminded that memoranda summarizing the presentation must: (1) List
                all persons attending or otherwise participating in the meeting at
                which the ex parte presentation was made; and (2) summarize all data
                presented and arguments made during the presentation. If the
                presentation consisted in whole or in part of the presentation of data
                or arguments already reflected in the presenter's written comments,
                memoranda or other filings in the proceeding, the presenter may provide
                citations to such data or arguments in his or her prior comments,
                memoranda, or other filings (specifying the relevant page and/or
                paragraph numbers where such data or arguments can be found) in lieu of
                summarizing them in the memorandum. Documents shown or given to
                Commission staff during ex parte meetings are deemed to be written ex
                parte presentations and must be filed consistent with Sec. 1.1206(b)
                of the Commission's rules. In proceedings governed by Sec. 1.49(f) of
                the Commission's rules, or for which the Commission has made available
                a method of electronic filing, written ex parte presentations and
                memoranda summarizing oral ex parte presentations, and all attachments
                thereto, must be filed through the Commission's Electronic Comment
                Filing System (ECFS) available for that proceeding, and must be filed
                in their native format (e.g., .doc, .xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf).
                Participants in this proceeding should familiarize themselves with the
                Commission's ex parte rules.
                 88. Filing Requirements--Comments and Replies. Pursuant to
                Sec. Sec. 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission's rules, interested
                parties may file comments and reply comments on or before the dates
                indicated on the first page of this document. Comments may be filed
                using ECFS.
                 Electronic Filers: Comments may be filed electronically
                using the internet by accessing the ECFS: http://apps.fcc.gov/ecfs/.
                 Paper Filers: Parties who choose to file by paper must
                file an original and one copy of each filing.
                 Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by commercial
                overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal Service
                mail. All filings must be addressed to the Commission's Secretary,
                Office of the Secretary, Federal Communications Commission.
                 All hand-delivered or messenger-delivered paper filings
                for the Commission's Secretary must be delivered to FCC Headquarters at
                445 12th St. SW, Room TW-A325, Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours
                are 8:00 a.m. to 7:00 p.m. All hand deliveries must be held together
                with rubber bands or fasteners. Any envelopes and boxes must be
                disposed of before entering the building.
                 Commercial overnight mail (other than U.S. Postal Service
                Express Mail and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9050 Junction Drive,
                Annapolis Junction, MD 220701.
                U.S. Postal Service first-class, Express, and Priority
                mail must be addressed to 445 12th Street SW, Washington, DC 20554.
                 89. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Act Analysis. The Regulatory
                Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended (RFA), requires that a regulatory
                flexibility analysis be prepared for notice and comment rulemaking
                proceedings, unless the agency certifies that ``the rule will not, if
                promulgated, have a significant economic impact on a substantial number
                of small entities.'' The RFA generally defines the term ``small
                entity'' as having the same meaning as the terms ``small business,''
                ``small organization,'' and ``small governmental jurisdiction.'' In
                addition, the term ``small business'' has the same meaning as the term
                ``small business concern'' under the Small Business Act. A ``small
                business concern'' is one which: (1) Is independently owned and
                operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and (3)
                satisfies any additional criteria established by the Small Business
                Administration (SBA).
                 90. Written public comments are requested on the IFRA and must be
                filed in accordance with the same filing deadlines as comments on this
                NPRM, with a distinct heading designating them as responses to the
                IRFA. In
                [[Page 6756]]
                addition, a copy of this NPRM and the IRFA will be sent to the Chief
                Counsel for Advocacy of the SBA.
                 91. Paperwork Reduction Act. This NPRM seeks comment on whether the
                Commission should adopt new or modified information collection
                requirements. The Commission, as part of its continuing effort to
                reduce paperwork burdens and pursuant to the Paperwork Reduction Act of
                1995, invites the public and the Office of Management and Budget (OMB)
                to comment on these information collection requirements. In addition,
                pursuant to the Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, we seek
                specific comment on how we might further reduce the information
                collection burden for small business concerns with fewer than 25
                employees.
                 92. People with Disabilities. To request materials in accessible
                formats for people with disabilities (braille, large print, electronic
                files, audio format), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the
                Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at 202-418-0530 (voice), 202-
                418-0432 (tty).
                 93. Additional Information. For additional information on this
                proceeding, please contact Brendan Holland of the Media Bureau,
                Industry Analysis Division, Brendan.Holland@fcc.gov, (202) 418-2757.
                Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis
                 94. Need for, and Objective of, the Proposed Rules. This NPRM
                begins an examination of the Commission's media ownership rules and
                possible changes to these rules. As discussed in the NPRM, the
                Commission is required by statute to review its media ownership rules
                every four years to determine whether they ``are necessary in the
                public interest as the result of competition.'' Consistent with the
                Communications Act, the Commission must examine its media ownership
                rules and consider whether they continue to serve our public interest
                goals of competition, viewpoint diversity and localism, or whether they
                should be modified or eliminated. Specifically, the NPRM examines the
                three remaining media ownership rules, the Local Radio Ownership Rule,
                the Local Television Ownership Rule and the Dual Network Rule. In
                addition, the NPRM seeks comment on several proposals that were
                advanced in previous rulemakings and which the Commission indicated it
                would examine further in the context of this review of its structural
                ownership rules. These proposals, to extend cable procurement
                requirements to broadcasters, develop a model for market-based,
                tradeable ``diversity credits'' to serve as an alternative method for
                adopting ownership limits, and adopt formulas aimed at creating media
                ownership limits that promote diversity, are presented by their
                proponents as initiatives that could further the Commission's diversity
                goal. The Commission anticipates that these initiatives, if ultimately
                adopted, might benefit small entities.
                 95. Legal Basis. The proposed action is authorized under sections
                1, 2(a), 4(i), 303, 307, 309, and 310 of the Communications Act of
                1934, as amended, and section 202(h) of the Telecommunications Act of
                1996.
                 96. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to
                which the Proposed Rules Apply. The RFA directs agencies to provide a
                description of, and where feasible, an estimate of the number of small
                entities that may be affected by the proposed rule revisions, if
                adopted. The RFA generally defines the term ``small entity'' as having
                the same meaning as the terms ``small business,'' ``small
                organization,'' and ``small governmental jurisdiction.'' In addition,
                the term ``small business'' has the same meaning as the term ``small
                business concern'' under the Small Business Act (SBA). A small business
                concern is one which: (1) Is independently owned and operated; (2) is
                not dominant in its field of operation; and (3) satisfies any
                additional criteria established by the SBA. Below, we provide a
                description of such small entities, as well as an estimate of the
                number of such small entities, where feasible.
                 97. Television Broadcasting. According to the U.S. Census Bureau
                2017 NAICS Definitions, this U.S. Economic Census category ``comprises
                establishments primarily engaged in broadcasting images together with
                sound.'' These establishments operate television broadcast studios and
                facilities for the programming and transmission of programs to the
                public. These establishments also produce or transmit visual
                programming to affiliated broadcast television stations, which in turn
                broadcast the programs to the public on a predetermined schedule.
                Programming may originate in their own studio, from an affiliated
                network, or from external sources. The SBA has created the following
                small business size standard for such businesses: those having $38.5
                million or less in annual receipts. The 2012 Economic Census reports
                that 751 firms in this category operated in that year. Of that number,
                656 had annual receipts of $25 million or less, 25 had annual receipts
                between $25 million and $49,999,999 and 70 had annual receipts of $50
                million or more. Based on this data, the Commission estimates that the
                majority of commercial television broadcast stations are small entities
                under the applicable size standard.
                 98. Additionally, the Commission has estimated the number of
                licensed commercial television stations to be 1,349. Of this total,
                1,248 stations (or about 92.5 percent) had revenues of $38.5 million or
                less, according to Commission staff review of the BIA Kelsey Inc. Media
                Access Pro Television Database (BIA) in November 2018, and therefore
                these stations qualify as small entities under the SBA definition.
                 99. Radio Broadcasting. This U.S. Economic Census category
                ``comprises establishments primarily engaged in broadcasting aural
                programs by radio to the public.'' Programming may originate in their
                own studio, from an affiliated network, or from external sources. The
                SBA has created the following small business size standard for such
                businesses: those having $38.5 million or less in annual receipts.
                Economic Census data for 2012 show that 2,849 firms in this category
                operated in that year. Of that number, 2,806 operated with annual
                receipts of less than $25 million per year, 17 with annual receipts
                between $25 million and $49,999,999 and 26 with annual receipts of $50
                million or more. Based on this data, we estimate that the majority of
                commercial radio broadcast stations were small under the applicable SBA
                size standard.
                 100. Apart from the U.S. Economic Census, the Commission has
                estimated the number of licensed commercial AM radio stations to be
                4,426 stations and the number of commercial FM radio stations to be
                6,737, for a total number of 11,364. Of this total, 11,355 stations (or
                99.9 percent) had revenues of $38.5 million or less, according to
                Commission staff review of the BIA Kelsey Inc. Media Access Pro
                Television Database (BIA) in November 2018, and therefore these
                stations qualify as small entities under the SBA definition.
                 101. In assessing whether a business concern qualifies as small
                under the above definition, business (control) affiliations must be
                included. Our estimate, therefore, likely overstates the number of
                small entities that might be affected by our action because the revenue
                figure on which it is based does not include or aggregate revenues from
                affiliated companies. In addition, an element of the definition of
                ``small business'' is that the entity not be dominant in its field of
                operation. We are unable at this time to define or quantify the
                criteria that would establish whether a specific radio or
                [[Page 6757]]
                television station is dominant in its field of operation. Accordingly,
                the estimate of small businesses to which the proposed rules may apply
                does not exclude any radio or television station from the definition of
                small business on this basis and is therefore possibly over-inclusive.
                 102. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and other
                Compliance Requirements. The proposals, if ultimately adopted, would
                require modification of several Commission forms and their
                instructions: (1) FCC Form 301, Application for Construction Permit for
                Commercial Broadcast Station; (2) FCC Form 314, Application for Consent
                to Assignment of Broadcast Station Construction Permit or License; and
                (3) FCC Form 315, Application for Consent to Transfer Control of
                Corporation Holding Broadcast Station Construction Permit or License.
                The Commission also would modify, as necessary, other forms that
                include in their instructions the media ownership rules or citations to
                media ownership proceedings, including Form 303-S, Application for
                Renewal License for AM, FM, TV, Translator, or LPTV Station and Form
                323, Ownership Report for Commercial Broadcast Station. The impact of
                these changes will be the same on all entities, and we do not
                anticipate that compliance will require the expenditure of any
                additional resources or place additional burdens on small businesses.
                 103. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small
                Entities, and Significant--Alternatives Considered. The RFA requires an
                agency to describe any significant alternatives that it has considered
                in reaching its proposed approach, which may include the following four
                alternatives (among others): (1) The establishment of differing
                compliance or reporting requirements or timetables that take into
                account the resources available to small entities; (2) the
                clarification, consolidation, or simplification of compliance or
                reporting requirements under the rule for small entities; (3) the use
                of performance, rather than design, standards; and (4) an exemption
                from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for small entities.
                 104. The NPRM begins a statutorily mandated examination of whether
                three remaining media ownership rules remain in the public interest as
                a result of competition and promote the Commission's longstanding
                policy goals of competition, viewpoint diversity and localism. The NPRM
                acknowledges new technologies and changed marketplace conditions that
                affect whether the rules remain in the public interest considering
                competition and the need to allow broadcasters, including small
                entities, to achieve the economies of scale and scope necessary to
                continue to compete in a changed marketplace. The NPRM considers
                measures designed to minimize the economic impact of any changes to
                these rules on firms generally, as well as initiatives designed to
                promote broadcast ownership opportunities among a diverse group of
                owners, including small entities. The NPRM also invites comment on the
                effects of any rule changes on different types of broadcasters (e.g.,
                independent or network-affiliated), the benefits and costs associated
                with any proposals, and any potential to have significant impact on
                small entities.
                 105. The NPRM proposes no new reporting requirements, performance
                standards or other compliance obligations, although, as discussed
                above, it may modify, as necessary, certain existing reporting forms
                should it adopt any changes to its media ownership rules. Should the
                Commission ultimately adopt changes to its media ownership rules that
                could increase requirements or compliance burdens for small entities,
                it will determine whether possible exemptions, waiver opportunities,
                extended compliance deadlines or other measures would mitigate any
                potential impact on small entities.
                 106. Federal Rules that May Duplicate, Overlap or Conflict with the
                Proposed Rules. None.
                Ordering Clauses
                 107. Accordingly, it is ordered that, pursuant to the authority
                contained in sections 1, 2(a), 4(i), 257, 303, 307, 309, 310, and 403
                of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and section 202(h) of
                the Telecommunications Act of 1996, this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking
                is adopted.
                 108. It is further ordered, pursuant to applicable procedures set
                forth in Sec. Sec. 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission's rules,
                interested parties may file comments on the NPRM in MB Docket No. 18-
                349 on or before sixty (60) days after publication in the Federal
                Register and reply comments on or before ninety (90) days after
                publication in the Federal Register.
                 109. It is furthered ordered that the Commission's Consumer and
                Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a
                copy of this NPRM, including the IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for
                Advocacy of the Small Business Administration.
                Federal Communications Commission.
                Katura Jackson,
                Federal Register Liaison Officer, Office of the Secretary.
                [FR Doc. 2019-03278 Filed 2-27-19; 8:45 am]
                 BILLING CODE 6712-01-P
                

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT