Revision of the Commission's Program Access Rules

Federal Register, Volume 77 Issue 78 (Monday, April 23, 2012)

Federal Register Volume 77, Number 78 (Monday, April 23, 2012)

Proposed Rules

Pages 24302-24336

From the Federal Register Online via the Government Printing Office www.gpo.gov

FR Doc No: 2012-8991

Page 24301

Vol. 77

Monday,

No. 78

April 23, 2012

Part III

Federal Communications Commission

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

47 CFR Part 76

Revision of the Commission's Program Access Rules; Proposed Rule

Page 24302

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION

47 CFR Part 76

MB Docket Nos. 12-68, 07-18, and 05-192; FCC 12-30

Revision of the Commission's Program Access Rules

AGENCY: Federal Communications Commission.

ACTION: Proposed rule.

-----------------------------------------------------------------------

SUMMARY: In this document, the Commission seeks comment on whether to retain, sunset, or relax one of the several protections afforded to multichannel video programming distributors by the program access rules--the prohibition on exclusive contracts involving satellite-

delivered, cable-affiliated programming. The current exclusive contract prohibition is scheduled to expire on October 5, 2012. The Commission also seeks comment on potential revisions to its program access rules to better address alleged violations, including potentially discriminatory volume discounts and uniform price increases.

DATES: Comments are due on or before June 22, 2012; reply comments are due on or before July 23, 2012. Written PRA comments on the proposed information collection requirements contained herein must be submitted by the public, Office of Management and Budget (OMB), and other interested parties on or before June 22, 2012.

ADDRESSES: You may submit comments, identified by MB Docket Nos. 12-68, 07-18, and 05-192 by any of the following methods:

Federal Communications Commission's Web site: http://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs/. Follow the instructions for submitting comments.

Mail: Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by commercial overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal Service mail (although the Commission continues to experience delays in receiving U.S. Postal Service mail). All filings must be addressed to the Commission's Secretary, Office of the Secretary, Federal Communications Commission.

People with Disabilities: Contact the FCC to request reasonable accommodations (accessible format documents, sign language interpreters, CART, etc.) by email: FCC504@fcc.gov or phone: (202) 418-

0530 or TTY: (202) 418-0432.

In addition to filing comments with the Secretary, a copy of any PRA comments on the proposed information collection requirements contained herein should be submitted to the Federal Communications Commission via email to PRA@fcc.gov and to Nicholas A. Fraser, Office of Management and Budget, via email to Nicholas_A._Fraser@omb.eop.gov or via fax at (202) 395-5167. For detailed instructions for submitting comments and additional information on the rulemaking process, see the SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION section of this document.

FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT: For additional information, contact David Konczal, David.Konczal@fcc.gov, or Diana Sokolow, Diana.Sokolow@fcc.gov, of the Media Bureau, Policy Division, (202) 418-

2120. For additional information concerning the information collection requirements contained in this document, send an email to PRA@fcc.gov or contact Cathy Williams at (202) 418-2918. To view or obtain a copy of this information collection request (ICR) submitted to OMB: (1) Go to this OMB/GSA Web page: http://www.reginfo.gov/public/do/PRAMain, (2) look for the section of the Web page called ``Currently Under Review,'' (3) click on the downward-pointing arrow in the ``Select Agency'' box below the ``Currently Under Review'' heading, (4) select ``Federal Communications Commission'' from the list of agencies presented in the ``Select Agency'' box, (5) click the ``Submit'' button to the right of the ``Select Agency'' box, and (6) when the list of FCC ICRs currently under review appears, look for the OMB control number of this ICR as shown in the Supplementary Information section below (or its title if there is no OMB control number) and then click on the ICR Reference Number. A copy of the FCC submission to OMB will be displayed.

SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: This is a summary of document FCC 12-30, adopted and released on March 20, 2012. The full text is available for public inspection and copying during regular business hours in the FCC Reference Center, Federal Communications Commission, 445 12th Street SW., CY-A257, Washington, DC 20554. This document will also be available via ECFS (http://www.fcc.gov/cgb/ecfs/). Documents will be available electronically in ASCII, Word 97, and/or Adobe Acrobat. The complete text may be purchased from the Commission's copy contractor, 445 12th Street SW., Room CY-B402, Washington, DC 20554. To request this document in accessible formats (computer diskettes, large print, audio recording, and Braille), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the Commission's Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-

0530 (voice), (202) 418-0432 (TTY).

This document contains proposed information collection requirements. As part of its continuing effort to reduce paperwork burden and as required by the Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA) of 1995 (44 U.S.C. 3501-3520), the Federal Communications Commission invites the general public and other Federal agencies to comment on the following information collection(s). Public and agency comments are due June 22, 2012.

Comments should address: (a) Whether the proposed collection of information is necessary for the proper performance of the functions of the Commission, including whether the information shall have practical utility; (b) the accuracy of the Commission's burden estimates; (c) ways to enhance the quality, utility, and clarity of the information collected; and (d) ways to minimize the burden of the collection of information on the respondents, including the use of automated collection techniques or other forms of information technology; In addition, pursuant to the Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Public Law 107-198, see 44 U.S.C. 3506(c)(4), we seek specific comment on how we might ``further reduce the information collection burden for small business concerns with fewer than 25 employees.''

OMB Control Number: 3060-0888.

Title: Section 1.221, Notice of hearing; appearances; Section 1.229, Motions to enlarge, change, or delete issues; Section 1.248, Prehearing conferences; hearing conferences; Section 76.7, Petition Procedures; Section 76.9, Confidentiality of Proprietary Information; Section 76.61, Dispute Concerning Carriage; Section 76.914, Revocation of Certification; Section 76.1001, Unfair Practices; Section 76.1002, Specific Unfair Practices Prohibited; Section 76.1003, Program Access Proceedings; Section 76.1302, Carriage Agreement Proceedings; Section 76.1513, Open Video Dispute Resolution.

Form Number: Not applicable.

Type of Review: Revision of a currently approved collection.

Respondents: Businesses or other for-profit; not-for-profit institutions.

Number of Respondents and Responses: 828 respondents; 828 responses.

Estimated Time per Response: 6.8 to 98 hours.

Frequency of Response: On occasion reporting requirement; third party disclosure requirement.

Page 24303

Obligation to Respond: Required to obtain or retain benefits. The statutory authority for this collection of information is contained in sections 4(i), 303(r), 616, and 628 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended.

Total Annual Burden: 43,387 hours.

Total Annual Costs: $4,719,600.

Privacy Act Impact Assessment: No impact.

Nature and Extent of Confidentiality: A party that wishes to have confidentiality for proprietary information with respect to a submission it is making to the Commission must file a petition pursuant to the pleading requirements in Sec. 76.7 and use the method described in Sec. Sec. 0.459 and 76.9 to demonstrate that confidentiality is warranted.

Needs and Uses: On March 20, 2012, the Commission adopted a Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (``NPRM''), Revision of the Commission's Program Access Rules, MB Docket No. 12-68, FCC 12-30. In the NPRM, the Commission seeks comment on (i) whether to retain, sunset, or relax the prohibition on exclusive contracts between cable operators and satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming vendors; and (ii) potential revisions to the program access rules to better address alleged violations, including potentially discriminatory volume discounts and uniform price increases.

The NPRM proposes to add or revise the following rule sections, which contain proposed information collection requirements: 47 CFR 76.1002(c)(5), 47 CFR 76.1002(c)(7), 76.1003(e)(1).

If adopted, 47 CFR 76.1002(c)(5) would provide that, to the extent the exclusive contract prohibition sunsets or is relaxed, a cable operator, satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, or satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest must submit a ``Petition for Exclusivity'' to the Commission and receive approval from the Commission to preclude the filing of complaints alleging that an exclusive contract, or practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, with respect to areas served by a cable operator violates Section 628(b) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and Section 76.1001(a) of the Commission's Rules, or Section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and Section 76.1002(b) of the Commission's Rules. The proposed rule specifies the requirements for the petition for exclusivity, provides that a competing multichannel video programming distributor affected by the proposed exclusivity may file an opposition to the petition for exclusivity within thirty (30) days of the date on which the petition is placed on public notice, and provides that the petitioner may file a response within ten (10) days of receipt of any formal opposition.

If adopted, 47 CFR 76.1002(c)(7) would provide that, to the extent the exclusive contract prohibition is relaxed, a cable operator, satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, or satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest seeking to remove the prohibition on exclusive contracts and practices, activities or arrangements tantamount to an exclusive contract set forth in Section 76.1002(c)(2) of the Commission's Rules may submit a ``Petition for Sunset'' to the Commission. If the Commission finds that the prohibition is not necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming, then the prohibition set forth in Section 76.1002(c)(2) of the Commission's Rules shall no longer apply in the geographic area specified in the decision of the Commission. The proposed rule specifies the requirements for the petition for sunset, provides that a competing multichannel video programming distributor or other interested party affected by the petition for sunset may file an opposition to the petition within forty-five (45) days of the date on which the petition is placed on public notice, and provides that the petitioner may file a response within fifteen (15) days of receipt of any formal opposition.

If adopted, 47 CFR 76.1003(e)(1) would provide that a cable operator, satellite cable programming vendor, or satellite broadcast programming vendor upon which a program access complaint is served shall answer within forty-five (45) days of service of the complaint if the complaint alleges a violation of Section 628(b) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, or Section 76.1001(a) of the Commission's rules. In addition, to the extent the exclusive contract prohibition sunsets or is relaxed, an increase in the number of complaints alleging a violation of Section 628(b) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, or Section 76.1001(a) of the Commission's rules is expected.

The Commission is seeking OMB approval for the proposed information collection requirements. All other remaining existing information collection requirements would stay as they are, and the various burden estimates would be revised to reflect the new and revised rules noted above.

Summary of the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking

  1. Introduction

    We issue this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (``NPRM'') to seek comment on (i) whether to retain, sunset, or relax one of the several protections afforded to multichannel video programming distributors (``MVPDs'') by the program access rules--the prohibition on exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming; and (ii) potential revisions to our program access rules to better address alleged violations, including potentially discriminatory volume discounts and uniform price increases. This NPRM promotes the goals of Executive Order 13579 and the Commission's plan adopted thereto, whereby the Commission analyzes rules that may be outmoded, ineffective, insufficient, or excessively burdensome and determines whether any such regulations should be modified, streamlined, expanded, or repealed.

    2. In areas served by a cable operator, Section 628(c)(2)(D) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended (the ``Act''), generally prohibits exclusive contracts for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming between any cable operator and any cable-affiliated programming vendor (the ``exclusive contract prohibition'').\1\ The exclusive contract prohibition applies to all satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming and presumes that an exclusive contract will cause competitive harm in every case, regardless of the type of programming at issue. The exclusive contract prohibition applies only to programming which is delivered via satellite; it does not apply to programming which is delivered via

    Page 24304

    terrestrial facilities.\2\ In January 2010, the Commission adopted rules providing for the processing of complaints alleging that an ``unfair act'' involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated programming violates Section 628(b) of the Act. Thus, while an exclusive contract involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming is generally prohibited, an exclusive contract involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated programming is permitted unless the Commission finds in response to a complaint that it violates Section 628(b) of the Act.

    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    \1\ See 47 U.S.C. 548(c)(2)(D). An exclusive contract for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming between a cable operator and a cable-affiliated programming vendor that provides satellite-delivered programming would violate Section 628(c)(2)(D) even if the cable operator that is a party to the contract is not affiliated with the cable-affiliated programming vendor that is a party to the contract. See Implementation of the Cable Television Consumer Protection and Competition Act of 1992--

    Development of Competition and Diversity in Video Programming Distribution: Section 628(c)(5) of the Communications Act: Sunset of Exclusive Contract Prohibition, Report and Order, 22 FCC Rcd 17791, 17840-41, paras. 70-72 (2007) (``2007 Extension Order''), aff'd sub nom. Cablevision Sys. Corp. et al. v. FCC, 597 F.3d 1306, 1314-15 (D.C. Cir. 2010) (``Cablevision I''); see also Cable Horizontal and Vertical Ownership Limits, Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 23 FCC Rcd 2134, 2195-96, para. 145 (2008).

    \2\ In this NPRM, we refer to ``satellite cable programming'' and ``satellite broadcast programming'' collectively as ``satellite-

    delivered programming.''

    ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    3. In Section 628(c)(5) of the Act, Congress provided that the exclusive contract prohibition would cease to be effective on October 5, 2002, unless the Commission found that it ``continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.'' In June 2002, the Commission found that the exclusive contract prohibition continued to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity and retained the exclusive contract prohibition for five years, until October 5, 2007. The Commission provided that, during the year before the expiration of the five-year extension, it would conduct a second review to determine whether the exclusive contract prohibition continued to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming. After conducting such a review, the Commission in September 2007 concluded that the exclusive contract prohibition was still necessary, and it retained the prohibition for five more years, until October 5, 2012. The Commission again provided that, during the year before the expiration of the five-year extension, it would conduct a third review to determine whether the exclusive contract prohibition continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.

    4. Accordingly, in this NPRM, we initiate the third review of the necessity of the exclusive contract prohibition. Below, we present certain data on the current state of competition in the video distribution market and the video programming market, and we invite commenters to submit more recent data or empirical analyses. We seek comment on whether current conditions in the video marketplace support retaining, sunsetting, or relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition. To the extent that the data do not support retaining the exclusive contract prohibition as it exists today, we seek comment on whether we can preserve and protect competition in the video distribution market by either:

    Sunsetting the exclusive contract prohibition in its entirety and instead relying solely on existing protections provided by the program access rules that will not sunset: (i) The case-by-case consideration of exclusive contracts pursuant to Section 628(b) of the Act; (ii) the prohibition on discrimination in Section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Act; and (iii) the prohibition on undue or improper influence in Section 628(c)(2)(A) of the Act; or

    Relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition by (i) establishing a process whereby a cable operator or satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer can seek to remove the prohibition on a market-by-market basis based on the extent of competition in the market; (ii) retaining the prohibition only for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated Regional Sports Networks (``RSNs'') and any other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming that the record here establishes as being important for competition and non-replicable and having no good substitutes; and/or (iii) other ways commenters propose.

    We seek comment also on (i) how to implement a sunset (complete or partial) to minimize any potential disruption to consumers; (ii) the First Amendment implications of the alternatives discussed herein; (iii) the costs and benefits of the alternatives discussed herein; and (iv) the impact of a sunset on existing merger conditions.

    5. In addition, we seek comment below on potential improvements to the program access rules to better address potential violations. With the exception of certain procedural revisions and the previous extensions of the exclusive contract prohibition, the program access rules have remained largely unchanged in the almost two decades since the Commission originally adopted them in 1993. We seek comment on, among other things, whether our rules adequately address potentially discriminatory volume discounts and uniform price increases and, if not, how these rules should be revised to address these concerns.

  2. Background

    1. Program Access Protections

      6. Congress adopted the program access provisions as part of the Cable Television Consumer Protection and Competition Act of 1992 (``1992 Cable Act''). Congress was concerned that, in order to compete effectively, new market entrants would need access to satellite-

      delivered, cable-affiliated programming. At that time, Congress found that increased horizontal concentration of cable operators and extensive vertical integration \3\ created an imbalance of power, both between cable operators and program vendors and between incumbent cable operators and their multichannel competitors. As a result of this imbalance of power, Congress determined that the development of competition among MVPDs was limited and consumer choice was restricted. Congress concluded that cable-affiliated programmers had the incentive and ability to favor their affiliated cable operators over other, unaffiliated, MVPDs with the effect that competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming would not be preserved and protected.

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      \3\ Vertical integration means the combined ownership of cable systems and suppliers of cable programming.

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      7. The program access provisions afford several protections to MVPDs in their efforts to compete in the video distribution market. Sections 628(b), 628(c)(1), and 628(d) of the Act grant the Commission broad authority to prohibit ``unfair acts'' of cable operators, satellite cable programming vendors in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, and satellite broadcast programming vendors that have the ``purpose or effect'' of ``hindering significantly or preventing'' any MVPD from providing ``satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming to subscribers or consumers.'' \4\ In addition to this broad grant of authority, Congress in Section 628(c)(2) of the Act required the Commission to adopt specific regulations to specify particular conduct that is prohibited by Section 628(b), i.e., certain unfair acts involving satellite-delivered, cable-

      affiliated programming. In contrast to Section 628(b), the unfair acts listed in Section 628(c)(2) pertaining to satellite-delivered programming are presumed to harm competition in every case, and MVPDs alleging such unfair acts are not required to demonstrate harm. First, Section 628(c)(2)(A) requires the Commission to prohibit efforts by cable operators to unduly influence the decision of cable-affiliated programming vendors that provide satellite-delivered programming to sell their programming to competitors (``undue influence'').

      Page 24305

      Second, Section 628(c)(2)(B) requires the Commission to prohibit discrimination among MVPDs by cable-affiliated programming vendors that provide satellite-delivered programming in the prices, terms, and conditions for sale of programming (``discrimination''). Third, Sections 628(c)(2)(C)-(D) require the Commission to prohibit exclusive contracts between cable operators and cable-affiliated programming vendors that provide satellite-delivered programming, subject to certain exceptions. In this proceeding, our focus is on the protection provided under Section 628(c)(2)(D), although we discuss the other statutory protections to the extent they bear on our consideration of whether to allow the exclusive contract provision to sunset.

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      \4\ Throughout this NPRM, we use the term ``unfair act'' as shorthand for the phrase ``unfair methods of competition or unfair or deceptive acts or practices.'' 47 U.S.C. 548(b); see 47 CFR 76.1001.

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    2. Enactment of the Exclusive Contract Prohibition With a Sunset Provision

      8. In the 1992 Cable Act, Congress drew a distinction between exclusive contracts for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming in areas not served by a cable operator as of October 5, 1992 (``unserved areas'') and areas served by a cable operator as of that date (``served areas''). In unserved areas, Congress adopted a per se prohibition on exclusive contracts between cable operators and satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers. In served areas, however, the prohibition on exclusive contracts is not absolute; rather, an exclusive contract is permissible if the Commission determines that it ``is in the public interest.'' Congress thus recognized that, in served areas, some exclusive contracts may serve the public interest by providing offsetting benefits to the video programming market or assisting in the development of competition among MVPDs. To enforce or enter into an exclusive contract in a served area, a cable operator or a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer must submit a ``Petition for Exclusivity'' to the Commission for approval.\5\

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      \5\ See 47 CFR 76.1002(c)(5). Ten Petitions for Exclusivity have been filed since enactment of the 1992 Cable Act. Of these petitions, two were granted, three were denied, and five were dismissed at the request of the parties. See New England Cable News Channel, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 9 FCC Rcd 3231 (1994) (granting exclusivity petition); Time Warner Cable, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 9 FCC Rcd 3221 (1994) (denying exclusivity petition for Courtroom Television (``Court TV'')); Outdoor Life Network and Speedvision Network, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 13 FCC Rcd 12226 (CSB 1998) (denying exclusivity petition for the Outdoor Life Network (``OLN'') and Speedvision Network (``Speedvision'')); Cablevision Industries Corp. and Sci-Fi Channel, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 10 FCC Rcd 9786 (CSB 1995) (denying exclusivity petition for the Sci-Fi Channel); NewsChannel, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 10 FCC Rcd 691 (CSB 1994) (granting exclusivity petition).

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      9. In addition to this prior approval process, Congress also recognized that exclusivity can be a legitimate business practice where there is sufficient competition. Accordingly, in Section 628(c)(5), Congress provided that the exclusive contract prohibition in served areas:

      Shall cease to be effective 10 years after the date of enactment of this section, unless the Commission finds, in a proceeding conducted during the last year of such 10-year period, that such prohibition continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.

      The 1992 Cable Act was enacted on October 5, 1992. Accordingly, the ``sunset provision'' of Section 628(c)(5) would have triggered the expiration of the exclusive contract prohibition on October 5, 2002, absent a Commission finding that the prohibition remained necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.

    3. 2002 Extension of the Exclusive Contract Prohibition

      10. In October 2001, approximately a year before the initial expiration of the exclusive contract prohibition, the Commission sought comment on whether the exclusive contract prohibition remained necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming. Ultimately, the Commission concluded that the prohibition remained ``necessary.'' The Commission explained that, based on marketplace conditions at the time, cable-affiliated programmers retained the incentive and ability to withhold programming from unaffiliated MVPDs with the effect that competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming would be impaired without the prohibition. The Commission found as follows:

      The competitive landscape of the market for the distribution of multichannel video programming has changed for the better since 1992. The number of MVPDs that compete with cable and the number of subscribers served by those MVPDs have increased significantly. We find, however, that the concern on which Congress based the program access provisions--that in the absence of regulation, vertically integrated programmers have the ability and incentive to favor affiliated cable operators over nonaffiliated cable operators and programming distributors using other technologies such that competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming would not be preserved and protected--persists in the current marketplace.

      11. Accordingly, the Commission extended the exclusive contract prohibition for five years (i.e., through October 5, 2007). The Commission provided that, during the year before the expiration of the five-year extension of the exclusive contract prohibition, it would conduct another review to determine whether the exclusive contract prohibition continued to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in distribution of video programming.

    4. 2007 Extension of the Exclusive Contract Prohibition and D.C. Circuit Decision

      12. In February 2007, the Commission again sought comment on whether the prohibition remained necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming. For a second time, the Commission concluded that the prohibition remained ``necessary.''

      13. The Commission conducted its analysis of the exclusive contract prohibition in five parts. First, in considering the applicable standard of review, the Commission determined that it may use its predictive judgment, economic theory, and specific factual evidence in determining whether, ``in the absence of the prohibition, competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming would not be preserved and protected.'' If such an inquiry is answered in the affirmative, then the Commission concluded that it must extend the exclusive contract prohibition. Second, the Commission examined the changes that had occurred in the video programming and distribution markets since 2002, and it found that, while there had been some procompetitive trends, the concerns on which Congress based the program access provisions persisted in the marketplace. Third, the Commission examined the incentive and ability of cable-affiliated programmers to favor their affiliated cable operators over competitive MVPDs with the effect that competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming would not be preserved and protected.\6\ The Commission determined that this incentive and ability existed with the effect that the exclusive contract prohibition remained necessary to preserve and protect

      Page 24306

      competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming. The Commission recognized, however, ``that Congress intended for the exclusive contract prohibition to sunset at a point when market conditions warrant'' and specifically ``cautioned competitive MVPDs to take any steps they deem appropriate to prepare for the eventual sunset of the prohibition, including further investments in their own programming.'' Fourth, the Commission considered commenters' arguments that the exclusive contract prohibition is both overinclusive and underinclusive with respect to the types of programming and MVPDs it covers, and the Commission declined either to narrow or broaden the prohibition. Fifth, the Commission considered the appropriate length of time for an extension of the exclusive contract prohibition, and it again concluded that the prohibition should be extended for five years.

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      \6\ For purposes of this NPRM, the term ``competitive MVPD'' refers to MVPDs that compete with incumbent cable operators in the video distribution market, such as DBS operators and wireline video providers.

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      14. Accordingly, the Commission extended the exclusive contract prohibition for five years (i.e., until October 5, 2012). As in 2002, the Commission provided that, during the year before the expiration of the five-year extension of the exclusive contract prohibition (i.e., between October 2011 and October 2012), it would conduct a third review to determine whether the exclusive contract prohibition continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.

      15. Cablevision Systems Corporation (``Cablevision'') and Comcast Corporation (``Comcast'') (Cablevision and Comcast, collectively, the ``Petitioners'') filed petitions for review of the 2007 Extension Order with the D.C. Circuit. The D.C. Circuit addressed Petitioners' objections to three conclusions that the Commission reached in the 2007 Extension Order. First, Petitioners objected to the Commission's interpretation of the term ``necessary'' as used in the sunset provision as requiring the exclusive contract prohibition to continue ``if, in the absence of the prohibition, competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming would not be preserved and protected.'' The D.C. Circuit found that the term ``necessary'' is ``not language of plain meaning'' and that the Commission's interpretation was ``well within the Commission's discretion'' under Chevron. Second, Petitioners contended that ``the Commission did not rely on substantial evidence when it concluded that vertically integrated cable companies would enter into competition-harming exclusive contracts if the exclusivity prohibition were allowed to lapse.'' The D.C. Circuit disagreed, finding that the Commission relied on substantial evidence and stating that ``conclusions based on the Commission's predictive judgment and technical analysis are just the type of conclusions that warrant deference from this Court.'' While there had been substantial changes in the MVPD market since 1992, the court described the transformation as a ``mixed picture'' and deferred to the Commission's analysis, which concluded that vertically integrated cable companies retained a substantial ability and incentive to withhold ``must have'' programming. Finally, Petitioners objected to the Commission's failure to narrow the exclusive contract prohibition to apply only to certain types of cable companies or certain types of programming. The D.C. Circuit found that the Commission's decision to refrain from narrowing the exclusive contract prohibition was not arbitrary and capricious, but rather was a reasonable decision ``to adhere to Congress's statutory design.''

      16. While the D.C. Circuit affirmed the 2007 Extension Order, it also provided some comment on the Commission's subsequent review of the exclusive contract prohibition. Specifically, the D.C. Circuit stated as follows:

      We anticipate that cable's dominance in the MVPD market will have diminished still more by the time the Commission next reviews the prohibition, and expect that at that time the Commission will weigh heavily Congress's intention that the exclusive contract prohibition will eventually sunset. Petitioners are correct in pointing out that the MVPD market has changed drastically since 1992. We expect that if the market continues to evolve at such a rapid pace, the Commission will soon be able to conclude that the exclusive contract prohibition is no longer necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.

    5. TWC/Time Warner and Comcast/NBCU Transactions

      17. Since the 2007 Extension Order, two transactions have had a particular impact on the video distribution market and the video programming market: (i) The separation of Time Warner Cable Inc. (``TWC''; a cable operator) from Time Warner Inc. (``Time Warner''; an owner of satellite-delivered, national programming networks); \7\ and (ii) the joint venture between Comcast (a vertically integrated cable operator) and NBC Universal, Inc. (``NBCU''; an owner of broadcast stations and satellite-delivered, national programming networks).\8\

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      \7\ See Applications for Consent to the Assignment and/or Transfer of Control of Licenses, Time Warner Inc., Assignor/

      Transferor, and Time Warner Cable Inc., Assignee/Transferree, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 24 FCC Rcd 879 (MB, WCB, WTB, IB, 2009) (``Time Warner Order'').

      \8\ See Applications of Comcast Corporation, General Electric Company and NBC Universal, Inc. For Consent to Assign Licenses and Transfer Control of Licensees, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 26 FCC Rcd 4238 (2011) (``Comcast/NBCU Order'').

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      18. In the Time Warner Order, the Media, Wireline Competition, Wireless Telecommunications, and International Bureaus (the ``Bureaus'') granted the applications for the assignment and transfer of control of certain Commission licenses and authorizations from Time Warner to TWC. Before the transaction, Time Warner controlled TWC, but after their separation, Time Warner no longer has an ownership interest in TWC or its subsidiary licensees. As a result of the transaction, Time Warner's programming networks are no longer affiliated with TWC, thus reducing the number of satellite-delivered, national programming networks that are cable-affiliated. The Bureaus found that the transaction would benefit the public interest by lessening the extent to which TWC is vertically integrated and by eliminating Time Warner's vertical integration. In declining to adopt a condition applying the program access rules to Time Warner post-transaction, the Commission explained that the underlying premise of the program access rules would no longer apply because Time Warner and TWC would no longer have the incentive and ability to discriminate in favor of each other. If an MVPD believed that Time Warner or TWC violated the program access rules while they were vertically integrated, however, the Commission stated that the program access complaint process would provide an avenue for relief.

      19. In contrast, another recent transaction has led to an increased number of satellite-delivered, national programming networks that are cable-affiliated. In the Comcast/NBCU Order, the Commission granted the application of Comcast, General Electric Company (``GE''), and NBCU to assign and transfer control of broadcast, satellite, and other radio licenses from GE to Comcast. The transaction created a joint venture (``Comcast-NBCU'') combining NBCU's broadcast, cable programming, online content, movie studio, and other businesses with some of Comcast's cable programming and online content businesses. Before the transaction, both Comcast and NBCU either wholly or partly owned a number of satellite-

      Page 24307

      delivered, national programming networks. As a result of the transaction, programming networks that were previously affiliated with NBCU became affiliated with the joint venture, thus increasing the number of satellite-delivered, national programming networks that are cable-affiliated.

      20. In evaluating post-transaction MVPD access to Comcast-NBCU programming, the Commission concluded that the transaction ``creates the possibility that Comcast-NBCU, either temporarily or permanently, will block Comcast's video distribution rivals from access to the video programming content the joint venture would come to control or raise programming costs to its video distribution rivals.'' The Commission found the joint venture would ``have the power to implement an exclusionary strategy,'' and that ``successful exclusion * * * of video distribution rivals would likely harm competition by allowing Comcast to obtain or (to the extent it may already possess it) maintain market power.'' Additionally, the Commission concluded that an ``anticompetitive exclusionary program access strategy would often be profitable for Comcast.'' Accordingly, the Commission imposed conditions designed to ameliorate the potential harms, including a baseball-style arbitration condition that allows an aggrieved MVPD to submit a dispute with Comcast-NBCU over the terms and conditions of carriage of programming to commercial arbitration.

  3. Discussion

    1. Exclusive Contract Prohibition

      21. We seek comment on whether to retain, sunset, or relax the exclusive contract prohibition.\9\ Our discussion of this issue below proceeds in ten main parts. First, we present relevant data for assessing whether to retain, sunset, or relax the exclusive contract prohibition, and we invite commenters to submit more recent data or empirical analyses. Second, we ask commenters to assess whether these data, as updated and supplemented by commenters, support either retaining, sunsetting, or relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition. Third, we seek comment on how each of these three options (i.e., retaining, sunsetting, or relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition) will impact the creation of new national, regional, and local programming. Fourth, to the extent that the data do not support retaining the exclusive contract prohibition as it exists today, we seek comment on whether we can nonetheless preserve and protect competition in the video distribution market by either (i) sunsetting the prohibition in its entirety and relying solely on existing protections provided by the program access rules that will not sunset; or (ii) relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition, such as through removal of the prohibition on a market-by-market basis based on the extent of competition in the market or by retaining the prohibition only for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming. Fifth, we seek input on how a sunset (complete or partial) of the exclusive contract prohibition will impact consumers, and how to implement a sunset to minimize any potential disruption to consumers. Sixth, we ask commenters to assess whether and how each of the three options comports with the First Amendment. Seventh, we ask commenters to consider the costs and benefits associated with each of the three options. Eighth, to the extent the exclusive contract prohibition sunsets (wholly or partially), we propose to eliminate existing restrictions on exclusive subdistribution agreements between cable operators and satellite-

      delivered, cable-affiliated programmers. Ninth, we propose that any amendments we adopt herein to our rules pertaining to exclusive contracts between cable operators and satellite-delivered, cable-

      affiliated programmers in served areas will apply equally to existing rules pertaining to exclusive contracts involving common carriers and Open Video Systems (``OVS'') in served areas. Finally, we seek comment on how conditions adopted in previous merger orders may be impacted if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially).

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      \9\ Because the Commission seeks comment on alternative approaches to the exclusive contract prohibition--retaining, sunsetting, or relaxing (either through market-based petitions or retaining a prohibition for regional sports networks)--the Proposed Rules attached hereto include potential rule amendments based on each of these alternatives.

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      1. Relevant Data in Considering a Sunset of the Exclusive Contract Prohibition

      22. In evaluating whether the exclusive contract prohibition ``continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming,'' the Commission has previously examined data on the status of competition in the video programming market and the video distribution market. Specifically, in the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission examined ``the changes that had occurred in the programming and distribution markets since 2002 when the Commission last reviewed whether the exclusive contract prohibition continued to be necessary to preserve and protect competition.'' The Commission examined data relating to (i) the number of MVPD subscribers nationwide and in regional markets attributable to each category of MVPD, including cable operators, as well as the extent of regional clustering by cable operators; \10\ (ii) the number of satellite-delivered, national programming networks and the percentage of such networks that are cable-affiliated; and (iii) the number of regional programming networks and the percentage of such networks that are cable-affiliated. We believe it is appropriate to consider similar data in determining whether the exclusive contract prohibition remains necessary today. We also seek comment on whether our assessment of the exclusivity prohibition should consider data concerning other types of ``satellite cable programming.''

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      \10\ ``Clustering'' refers to ``an increase over time in the number of cable subscribers and homes passed by a single MSO in particular markets (accomplished via internal growth as well as by acquisitions).'' 2007 Extension Order, 22 FCC Rcd at 17831, para. 56.

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      23. In an effort to aid such an evaluation, we have prepared the tables in Appendices A through C of the NPRM, which contain data from previously released Commission documents as well as other sources. Appendices A through C are available at http://transition.fcc.gov/Daily_Releases/Daily_Business/2012/db0320/FCC-12-30A1.pdf. The first column of data, entitled ``1st Annual Report,'' focuses on data from the 1st Annual Report on video competition.\11\ The second column of data, entitled ``2002 Extension,'' focuses on data from the 2002 Extension Order.\12\ The third column of data, entitled ``2007 Extension,'' focuses on data from the 2007 Extension Order.\13\ The fourth and

      Page 24308

      final column of data, entitled ``Most Recent,'' focuses on the most recent data available. We believe that considering data from these four time periods will enable us to view the evolution of the video distribution and video programming markets over time. We invite commenters to submit more recent data in each of the categories identified, as well as data regarding the extent of regional clustering of cable operators, and any additional data the Commission should consider in its review.

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      \11\ Implementation of Section 19 of the Cable Television Consumer Protection and Competition Act of 1992: Annual Assessment of the Status of Competition in the Market for the Delivery of Video Programming, First Report, 9 FCC Rcd 7442 (1994) (``1st Annual Report'') (containing data as of 1994).

      \12\ Implementation of the Cable Television Consumer Protection and Competition Act of 1992--Development of Competition and Diversity in Video Programming Distribution: Section 628(c)(5) of the Communications Act: Sunset of Exclusive Contract Prohibition, Report and Order, 17 FCC Rcd 12124 (2002) (``2002 Extension Order'') (citing data from the Annual Assessment of the Status of Competition in the Market for the Delivery of Video Programming, Eighth Annual Report, 17 FCC Rcd 1244 (2002) (containing data as of June 2001) (``8th Annual Report'')).

      \13\ See 2007 Extension Order, 22 FCC Rcd 17791 (citing data from the Annual Assessment of the Status of Competition in the Market for the Delivery of Video Programming, Twelfth Annual Report, 21 FCC Rcd 2503 (2006) (containing data as of June 2005) (``12th Annual Report'')).

      ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      1. Nationwide and Regional MVPD Subscribership

        24. In past reviews of the exclusive contract prohibition, the Commission has assessed the percentage of MVPD subscribers nationwide that are attributable to each category of MVPD, including cable operators. The data in Appendix A indicate that the percentage of MVPD subscribers nationwide attributable to cable operators has declined over time, with the current percentage at approximately 58.5 percent, a decrease of 8.5 percentage points since the 2007 Extension Order. On a regional basis, the market share held by cable operators in Designated Market Areas (``DMAs'') varies considerably, from a high in the 80 percent range to a low in the 20 percent range.

        25. We seek comment on the extent to which we should consider online distributors of video programming in our analysis. The Commission recently stated that online distributors of video programming ``offer a tangible opportunity to bring customers substantial benefits'' and that they ``can provide and promote more programming choices, viewing flexibility, technological innovation and lower prices.'' While the Commission concluded that consumers today do not perceive online distributors as a substitute for traditional MVPD service, it stated that online distributors are a ``potential competitive threat'' and that they ``must have a similar array of programming'' if they are to ``fully compete against a traditional MVPD.'' In addition, in connection with the Commission's forthcoming 14th Annual Report on video competition, the Commission sought comment on the emergence of online video distributors.\14\ In light of possible cord-cutting and cord-shaving trends, we ask commenters to provide information regarding the effect that online distributors have had, or may have, on nationwide and regional MVPD subscription rates. Our task under Section 628(c)(5) is to determine whether the exclusive contract prohibition is necessary to preserve and protect ``competition,'' not competitors. Thus, to the extent that we conclude that competition in the video distribution market and the video programming market is currently sufficient to warrant sunsetting or relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition, how, if at all, should the emergence of a new category of potential competitor that could benefit from the exclusive contract prohibition impact our analysis?

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

        \14\ See Annual Assessment of the Status of Competition in the Market for the Delivery of Video Programming, Further Notice of Inquiry, 26 FCC Rcd 14091, 14112-13, paras. 52-55 (2011) (``Further Notice for the 14th Report'').

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      2. Satellite-Delivered, Cable-Affiliated, National Programming Networks

        26. In past reviews of the exclusive contract prohibition, the Commission has assessed the percentage of satellite-delivered, national programming networks that are cable-affiliated and the number of cable-

        affiliated networks that are among the Top 20 satellite-delivered, national programming networks as ranked by either subscribership or prime time ratings. The data in Appendix B indicate that, since the 2007 Extension Order, (i) the percentage of satellite-delivered, national programming networks that are cable-affiliated has declined from 22 percent to approximately 14.4 percent; (ii) the number of cable-affiliated networks among the Top 20 satellite-delivered, national programming networks as ranked by subscribership has increased from six to seven; and (iii) the number of cable-affiliated networks among the Top 20 satellite-delivered, national programming networks as ranked by average prime time ratings has remained at seven. We note that the calculation of the percentage of satellite-delivered, national programming networks that are cable-affiliated is based on our estimate of a total of 800 satellite-delivered, national programming networks available to MVPDs today.\15\ We seek comment on the reasonableness of this estimate and how, if at all, it should be revised. We also note that these data include satellite-delivered, national programming networks affiliated with Comcast, many of which (i.e., the ``Comcast-

        controlled networks'') are subject to program access conditions adopted in the Comcast/NBCU Order and will continue to be subject to these conditions for six more years (until January 2018, assuming they are not modified earlier in response to a petition) even if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset.\16\ If the

        Page 24309

        Comcast-controlled networks are excluded, the data in Appendix B indicate that, since the 2007 Extension Order, (i) the percentage of satellite-delivered, national programming networks that are cable-

        affiliated has declined from 22 percent to approximately 11 percent; (ii) the number of cable-affiliated networks among the Top 20 satellite-delivered, national programming networks as ranked by subscribership has remained at six; and (iii) the number of cable-

        affiliated networks among the Top 20 satellite-delivered, national programming networks as ranked by average prime time ratings has fallen from seven to five. We seek comment on whether and how to account for different versions of the same network in our analysis. For example, to the extent a particular network is available in standard definition (``SD''), high definition (``HD''), 3D, and video-on-demand (``VOD''), should this be counted as four different networks for purposes of our analysis? If so, and if both cable-affiliated and unaffiliated networks are treated similarly, how will this impact the percentage of networks that are cable-affiliated?

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

        \15\ In the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission found that 22 percent of satellite-delivered, national programming networks were affiliated with cable operators. See 2007 Extension Order, 22 FCC Rcd at 17802-03, para. 18. This percentage was based on a total of 531 satellite-delivered, national programming networks, as stated in the 12th Annual Report. See 12th Annual Report, 21 FCC Rcd at 2509-

        10, para. 21 and 2575, para. 157 (containing data as of June 2005). For purposes of the analysis in this NPRM, we increase this figure to 800 based on two factors. First, since 2005, we estimate that approximately 150 high-definition versions of networks previously provided only in standard definition have been launched. See SNL Kagan, High-Definition Cable Networks Getting More Carriage, Feb. 17, 2009; NCTA, Cable Networks, available at http://www.ncta.com/Organizations.aspx? type=orgtyp2&contentId=2907. Second, we estimate a net addition of approximately 100 networks, reflecting the increase over time in the number of national programming networks. See 2007 Extension Order, 22 FCC Rcd at 17836-37, para. 64 (noting the increase in national programming networks over time); Annual Assessment of the Status of Competition in the Market for the Delivery of Video Programming, Thirteenth Annual Report, 24 FCC Rcd 542, 550, para. 20 (2009) (``13th Annual Report'') (noting an increase of 34 programming networks between June 2005 and June 2006); id. at 731-36, Table C-4 (listing planned networks); SNL Kagan, Economics of Basic Cable Networks (2011 Edition), at 27 (listing cable networks launched after 2005).

        \16\ See Comcast/NBCU Order, 26 FCC Rcd at 4358, Appendix A, Condition II. The program access conditions reflected in Condition II apply to ``C-NBCU Programmers,'' which are defined as ``Comcast, C-NBCU, their Affiliates and any entity for which Comcast or C-NBCU manages or controls the licensing of Video Programming and/or any local broadcast television station on whose behalf Comcast or NBCU negotiates retransmission consent.'' Id. at 4356, Appendix A, Definitions. An ``Affiliate'' of any person means ``any person directly or indirectly controlling, controlled by, or under common control with, such person at the time at which the determination of affiliation is being made.'' Id. at 4355, Appendix A, Definitions. The issue of whether a particular cable network qualifies as a ``C-

        NBCU Programmer'' subject to these conditions is a fact-specific determination. For purposes of the estimates in this NPRM, and with the exception of the iN DEMAND networks discussed below, we assume that any network in which Comcast or NBCU holds a 50 percent or greater interest is a ``C-NBCU Programmer'' subject to these conditions. See Appendix B, Table 2 and Appendix C, Table 2 (available at http://transition.fcc.gov/Daily_Releases/Daily_Business/2012/db0320/FCC-12-30A1.pdf). We refer to these networks as ``Comcast-controlled networks.'' We refer to other networks in which Comcast or NBCU holds a less than 50 percent interest as ``Comcast-

        affiliated networks,'' which we assume for purposes of the estimates in this NPRM are not ``C-NBCU Programmers'' subject to the program access conditions adopted in the Comcast/NBCU Order, but are subject to the program access rules, including the exclusive contract prohibition. See id. Although Comcast has stated that it has a 53.7 percent interest in iN DEMAND, it has also stated that it ``cannot control decisionmaking at iN DEMAND.'' See Application of General Electric and Comcast, MB Docket No. 10-56 (Jan. 28, 2010), at 20 (stating that Comcast has a 53.7 percent interest in iN DEMAND) (``GE/Comcast/NBCU Application''); Letter from Michael H. Hammer, Counsel for Comcast, to Marlene H. Dortch, FCC, MB Docket No. 10-56 (Oct. 22, 2010), at 2 n.5. Accordingly, for purposes of the estimates in this NPRM, we consider the iN DEMAND networks to be ``Comcast-affiliated'' networks, and not ``Comcast-controlled'' networks subject to the program access conditions adopted in the Comcast/NBCU Order. Nothing in this NPRM should be read to state or imply any position as to whether any particular network qualifies or does not qualify as a ``C-NBCU Programmer.''

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

      3. Satellite-Delivered, Cable-Affiliated, Regional Programming Networks

        27. In addition to national programming networks, the Commission in past reviews of the exclusive contract prohibition has assessed the extent to which regional programming networks are cable-affiliated. As an initial matter, we note that some regional networks may be terrestrially delivered and therefore not subject to the exclusive contract prohibition applicable to satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programming. The data in Appendix C pertaining to regional networks do not distinguish between terrestrially delivered and satellite-delivered networks. We ask commenters to provide data regarding which cable-affiliated, regional programming networks, including RSNs, are satellite-delivered and which are terrestrially delivered.

        28. For purposes of our analysis, we distinguish between RSNs and other regional networks. The Commission has previously held that RSNs have no good substitutes, are important for competition, and are non-

        replicable. As set forth in Appendix C, recent data indicate that the number of RSNs that are cable-affiliated has increased from 18 to 31 (not including HD versions) since the 2007 Extension Order, and the percentage of all RSNs that are cable-affiliated has increased from 46 percent to approximately 52.3 percent. Are there networks that satisfy the Commission's definition of an RSN that are not included in the list of RSNs in Appendix C, such as certain local and regional networks that show NCAA Division I college football and basketball games? Should we include these and other similar networks, including unaffiliated networks, in our list of RSNs in Appendix C? In addition, are there networks included in the list of RSNs in Appendix C that do not satisfy the Commission's definition of an RSN? For example, do networks such as the Big Ten Network, PAC-12 Network, and The Mtn.--Mountain West Sports Network, which show NCAA Division I college football and basketball games of a particular college conference but not necessarily those of a particular team, satisfy the Commission's definition of an RSN? As required by this definition, do these and similar networks (i) distribute programming in ``a limited geographic region'' and (ii) carry the minimum amount of covered programming for an individual sports team.

        29. We note that the figures in Appendix C include RSNs that are affiliated with Comcast, many of which are subject to program access conditions adopted in the Comcast/NBCU Order and which will continue to be subject to these conditions for six more years (until January 2018, assuming they are not modified earlier in response to a petition) even if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset. If the Comcast-

        controlled RSNs are excluded, the data in Appendix C indicate that the number of RSNs that are cable-affiliated has increased from 18 to 22 (not including HD versions) since the 2007 Extension Order, and the percentage of RSNs that are cable-affiliated has decreased slightly from 46 percent to approximately 44.1 percent. With respect to non-RSN regional programming, we ask commenters to provide recent data on the number of these networks and the percentage of them that are cable-

        affiliated.

      4. Other Types of Cable-Affiliated ``Satellite Cable Programming''

        30. While the Commission in past reviews of the exclusive contract prohibition has considered linear and VOD programming networks, we also seek comment on whether there are other types of ``satellite cable programming'' or ``satellite broadcast programming'' that we should consider in assessing the exclusive contract prohibition. The Act defines ``satellite cable programming'' as (i) ``video programming'' (ii) which is ``transmitted via satellite'' and (iii) which is ``primarily intended for the direct receipt by cable operators for their retransmission to cable subscribers.'' The Act defines ``video programming'' as ``programming provided by, or generally considered comparable to programming provided by, a television broadcast station.'' Are cable operators affiliated with forms of ``video programming'' that meet the other two requirements of the definition of ``satellite cable programming,'' but that are not necessarily considered programming ``networks''? For example, to the extent that cable operators own or are affiliated with film libraries and other content, to what extent does this content qualify as ``satellite cable programming''? If so, how should this factor into our consideration of the exclusive contract prohibition?

        2. Assessing Whether the Data Support Retaining, Sunsetting, or Relaxing the Exclusive Contract Prohibition

        31. We seek comment on whether the data set forth herein, as updated and supplemented by commenters, support retaining, sunsetting, or relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition. In addition to the specific questions stated herein, we seek comment on any new trends in the industry or any other issues that are relevant to our determination of whether the status of the MVPD marketplace today supports the sunset of the exclusive contract prohibition. We specifically seek comment on the effect of the development of online video on the marketplace. We also request information on the impact of the Comcast/NBCU and TWC/Time Warner transactions on the MVPD marketplace. To what extent, if any, should these transactions inform our analysis of whether to retain, sunset, or relax the exclusive contract prohibition? What other recent developments in the MVPD market since our 2007 review should we consider in deciding whether to retain, sunset, or relax the exclusive contract prohibition?

        Page 24310

        32. In analyzing whether the exclusive contract prohibition remains necessary, the Commission has stated that it will ``assess whether, in the absence of the exclusive contract prohibition, vertically integrated programmers would have the ability and incentive to favor their affiliated cable operators over nonaffiliated competitive MVPDs and, if so, whether such behavior would result in a failure to protect and preserve competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.'' Accordingly, in light of the data noted above and as updated and supplemented by commenters, we seek comment on whether cable-affiliated programmers would have the ability and incentive to favor their affiliated cable operators absent the exclusive contract prohibition in today's marketplace with the effect that competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming would not be preserved and protected. How has the exclusive contract prohibition impacted the general state of competition among MVPDs in the video distribution market? How would a sunset or relaxation of the exclusive contract prohibition affect consumers and competition in the video distribution market, and how would a sunset or relaxation affect the potential entry of new competitors in the market? Is there any basis for treating satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming and terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated programming differently with respect to the exclusive contract prohibition? Are there differences between satellite-delivered programming and terrestrially delivered programming that would result in cable operators having a greater ability and incentive to favor affiliates providing satellite-delivered programming that warrants extension of the exclusive contract prohibition? To the extent the data support retaining the exclusive contract prohibition as it exists today, we seek comment on the appropriate length of an extension. Should the sunset date be five years from the current sunset date (i.e., until October 5, 2017), consistent with the two prior five-year extensions?

      5. Ability

        33. In assessing whether cable-affiliated programmers have the ``ability'' to favor their affiliated cable operators with the effect that competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming would not be preserved and protected, the Commission has explained that it considers whether satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming remains programming that is necessary for competition and for which there are no good substitutes. In the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission found that there were no good substitutes for certain satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming, and that such programming remained necessary for viable competition in the video distribution market. Accordingly, the Commission concluded that cable-

        affiliated programmers retained ``the ability to favor their affiliated cable operators over competitive MVPDs such that competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming would not be preserved and protected absent the rule.'' In reaching this conclusion, the Commission explained that ``what is most significant to our analysis is not the percentage of total available programming that is vertically integrated with cable operators, but rather the popularity of the programming that is vertically integrated and how the inability of competitive MVPDs to access this programming will affect the preservation and protection of competition in the video distribution marketplace.'' Moreover, the Commission acknowledged that ``there exists a continuum of vertically integrated programming, `ranging from services for which there may be substitutes (the absence of which from a rival MVPD's program lineup would have little impact), to those for which there are imperfect substitutes, to those for which there are no close substitutes at all (the absence of which from a rival MVPD's program lineup would have a substantial negative impact).' ''

        34. We seek comment on whether competitive MVPDs' access to satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming remains necessary today to preserve and protect competition in the video distribution marketplace. Is there any basis to depart from the Commission's conclusion in the 2007 Extension Order that satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programming remains necessary for viable competition in the video distribution market? We seek comment on whether and how the continued decline in the number and percentage of national programming networks that are cable-affiliated should impact our analysis, if at all. Despite a similar decline between the 2002 Extension Order and the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission in the 2007 Extension Order nonetheless found that ``cable-affiliated programming continues to represent some of the most popular and significant programming available today'' and that ``vertically integrated programming, if denied to cable's competitors, would adversely affect competition in the video distribution market.'' Is this also true today, considering that the data in Appendices B and C indicate that, since the 2007 Extension Order, (i) the percentage of satellite-delivered, national programming networks that are cable-affiliated has declined from 22 percent to approximately 14.4 percent; (ii) the number of cable-

        affiliated networks among the Top 20 satellite-delivered, national programming networks as ranked by subscribership has increased from six to seven; (iii) the number of cable-affiliated networks among the Top 20 satellite-delivered, national programming networks as ranked by average prime time ratings has remained at seven; and (iv) the number of cable-affiliated RSNs has increased from 18 to 31 (not including HD versions)?

        35. To what extent should we consider Comcast-controlled networks in our review of the exclusive contract prohibition? Because these networks will continue to be subject to program access conditions adopted in the Comcast/NBCU Order for six more years (until January 2018, assuming they are not modified earlier in response to a petition) even if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset, is there any basis to consider them in assessing whether to retain, sunset, or relax the exclusive contract prohibition? With the Comcast-controlled networks excluded, the data in Appendices B and C indicate that, since the 2007 Extension Order, (i) the number of cable-affiliated networks among the Top 20 satellite-delivered, national programming networks as ranked by subscribership has remained at six; (ii) the number of cable-

        affiliated networks among the Top 20 satellite-delivered, national programming networks as ranked by average prime time ratings has fallen from seven to five; and (iii) the number of cable-affiliated RSNs has increased from 18 to 21 (not including HD versions). With the Comcast-

        controlled networks excluded from the analysis, is it still accurate to characterize cable-affiliated programming as ``some of the most popular and significant programming available today,'' the absence of which from an MVPD's offering would ``adversely affect competition in the video distribution market.'' Rather than focusing on the number and percentage of networks that are cable-affiliated, is it more critical to assess the extent to which cable-affiliated programming remains popular and without substitutes? We note that, in the Comcast-NBCU Order, the Commission

        Page 24311

        found that the ``the loss of Comcast-NBCU programming * * * would harm rival video distributors, reducing their ability or incentive to compete with Comcast for subscribers'' and that ``this is particularly true for marquee programming, which includes a broad portfolio of national cable programming in addition to RSN and local broadcast programming; such programming is important to Comcast's competitors and without good substitutes from other sources.'' Is there any basis to reach a different conclusion with respect to satellite-

        delivered programming affiliated with other cable operators?

        36. We ask commenters contending that access to certain satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programming remains necessary to preserve and protect competition in the video distribution market to present reliable, empirical data supporting their positions, rather than merely labeling such programming as ``must have.'' While the Commission has recognized that some satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming has substitutes and that exclusive contracts involving such programming are unlikely to impact competition, are there certain categories of programming, such as RSNs, that we can presume have no close substitutes and that are necessary for competition? Does the wide variation in the importance and substitutability of satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programming call for a case-by-case or categorical assessment of programming, rather than a broad rule that applies to all programming equally?

        37. We also seek comment on whether a sunset of the exclusive contract prohibition would result in increased vertical integration in the video marketplace. If cable operators are permitted to enter into exclusive contracts with satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers, will this result in the acquisition of existing programming networks by cable operators, thereby increasing vertical integration? How can we accurately predict any such expected increase as we assess whether to retain, sunset, or relax the exclusive contract prohibition? Are cable operators more likely to acquire established networks that provide popular and non-substitutable programming, rather than creating new networks or investing in fledgling networks? Are there certain categories of programming networks that are more likely to be acquired or launched by cable operators? For example, we note that TWC recently announced that it will launch two RSNs in 2012 featuring the games of the Los Angeles Lakers, including the first Spanish-language RSN. Are cable operators expected to make further investments in RSNs in the future, especially if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset?

      6. Incentive

        38. In evaluating whether vertically integrated programmers retain the incentive to favor their affiliated cable operators over competitive MVPDs, the Commission analyzes ``whether there continues to be an economic rationale for vertically integrated programmers to engage in exclusive agreements with cable operators that will cause anticompetitive harms.'' The Commission has explained that, if a vertically integrated cable operator withholds programming from competitors, it can recoup profits lost at the upstream level (i.e., lost licensing fees and advertising revenues) by increasing the number of subscribers of its downstream MVPD division. The Commission explained that, particularly ``where competitive MVPDs are limited in their market share, a cable-affiliated programmer will be able to recoup a substantial amount, if not all, of the revenues foregone by pursuing a withholding strategy.'' Moreover, in the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission provided an empirical analysis demonstrating that the profitability of withholding increases as the number of television households passed by a vertically integrated cable operator increases in a given market area, such as through clustering.

        39. The Commission concluded in the 2007 Extension Order that market developments since 2002 did not yet support the lifting of the exclusive contract prohibition, but ``there nevertheless may come a point when these developments will be sufficient to allow the prohibition to sunset.'' Similarly, in upholding the 2007 Extension Order, the D.C. Circuit stated its expectation that, if the market continued evolving rapidly, the Commission could soon allow the exclusive contract prohibition to sunset, which Congress intended to occur at some point. We seek comment on whether now, almost five years since the most recent extension of the exclusive contract prohibition, we have reached such a point.

        40. As set forth in Appendix A, the percentage of MVPD subscribers nationwide attributable to cable operators has fallen since 2007, from an estimated 67 percent to approximately 58.5 percent today. Is there a certain market share threshold that, if reached, will render it unlikely for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers to withhold national networks from competitive MVPDs? We ask commenters to provide empirical analyses to support their positions. Has the decline in cable market share benefited consumers, such as through lower prices, or in some other way? If not, does that suggest that the level of competition in the video distribution market has not reached a point where the exclusive contract prohibition should sunset, or is the price of cable offerings determined by other factors?

        41. We also seek comment on how the current state of cable system clusters and cable market share in regional markets should affect our decision on whether to retain, sunset, or relax the exclusive contract prohibition. On a regional basis, the market share held by cable operators in DMAs varies considerably, from a high in the 80 percent range to a low in the 20 percent range. In some major markets, such as New York, Philadelphia, and Boston, the share of MVPD subscribers attributable to cable operators far exceeds the national cable market share of 67 percent deemed significant in the 2007 Extension Order. In other DMAs, such as Dallas, Denver, and Phoenix, data indicate that the share of MVPD subscribers attributable to cable operators is below 50 percent. How should this variation in regional market shares impact our analysis? Does this wide variation in cable market share on a regional and local basis call for a more granular assessment of the continued need for an exclusive contract prohibition in individual markets, rather than a broad rule that applies to all markets equally?

        42. The Commission stated in the 2002 Extension Order that ``clustering, accompanied by an increase in vertically integrated regional programming networks affiliated with cable MSOs that control system clusters, will increase the incentive of cable operators to practice anticompetitive foreclosure of access to vertically integrated programming.'' We seek comment on whether this conclusion remains valid today. In the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission found that the cable industry had continued to form regional clusters since the 2002 Extension Order. We note that a decrease in the amount of regional clustering could decrease the market share of individual cable operators within the footprints of regional programming, which would create fewer opportunities to implement exclusive arrangements. Has the amount of regional clustering increased or decreased since the 2007 Extension Order? We seek comment on whether events since the 2007 Extension Order mitigate or exacerbate the impact of

        Page 24312

        clustering. In the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission provided an empirical analysis demonstrating that the profitability of withholding increases as the number of television households passed by a vertically integrated cable operator increases in a given market area, such as through clustering. The analysis examined two vertically integrated cable operators on a DMA-by-DMA basis. Taking account of various factors, including the characteristics of the affiliated RSN and the profitability figures of the vertically integrated cable operator examined, the analysis identified multiple DMAs in which withholding would be profitable. In those DMAs, the homes passed by the vertically integrated cable operator as a percentage of television households ranged from 60-80 percent. We seek comment on this analysis and whether, based on current data, it continues to support retaining an exclusive contract prohibition, particularly in those markets where a vertically integrated cable operator passes a significant number of television households. We also note that the Commission in the 2007 Extension Order performed an analysis that concluded that withholding of some nationally distributed programming networks could be profitable if as little as 1.9 percent of non-cable subscribers were to switch to cable as a result of the withholding. We seek comment on this analysis and whether, based on current data, it continues to support retaining an exclusive contract prohibition for national programming networks.

        43. Has the current state of horizontal consolidation in the cable industry increased or decreased incentives for anticompetitive foreclosure of access to vertically integrated programming? We note that the data in Appendix A indicate that the percentage of MVPD subscribers receiving their video programming from one of the four largest vertically integrated cable MSOs has decreased from between 54 and 56.75 percent as stated in the 2007 Extension Order to approximately 42.8 percent today. What impact, if any, does this have on our review of the exclusive contract prohibition?

        3. Impact on the Video Programming Market

        44. We seek comment on how retaining, sunsetting, or relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition would impact the creation of new national, regional, and local programming and which of these options is most likely to increase programming diversity. What effect has the exclusive contract prohibition had on the incentives of incumbent cable operators to develop and produce video programming? Are incumbent cable operators less willing to invest in programming because they cannot enter into exclusive contracts and therefore must share their programming investment with their competitors? In the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission concluded that the extension of the exclusive contract prohibition would not create a disincentive for the creation of new programming. In support of this finding, the Commission noted that, despite the exclusive contract prohibition, the number of programming networks, including cable-affiliated networks, had increased since 1994. Is there any basis to conclude that the number of video programming networks, including cable-affiliated networks, would be even greater today if the exclusive contract prohibition had sunset earlier? Since the 2007 extension of the exclusive contract prohibition, has there been an increase or decrease in the development, promotion, and launch of new video programming services by incumbent cable operators? Would a sunset of the exclusive contract prohibition entice incumbent cable operators to invest in and launch new programming networks to compete with established networks, leading to greater diversity in the video programming market, or are incumbent cable operators more likely to acquire these established networks?

        45. What effect has the exclusive contract prohibition had on the incentives of competitive MVPDs and non-MVPD-affiliated programmers to develop and produce video programming? In the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission noted evidence that some competitive MVPDs had begun to invest in their own video programming, despite their ability to access satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming as a result of the exclusive contract prohibition. To what extent have competitive MVPDs invested in their own video programming? In the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission ``cautioned competitive MVPDs to take any steps they deem appropriate to prepare for the eventual sunset of the prohibition, including further investments in their own programming.'' Have competitive MVPDs made further investments in their own programming since that time? If the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), would competitive MVPDs be likely to increase their investment in video programming in order to ensure that they have a robust offering of programming to counteract any exclusive deals that incumbent cable operators might enter into with their affiliated programmers? We note that certain competitive MVPDs are currently subject to the exclusive contract prohibition, such as those that are cable operators or common carriers that provide video programming directly to subscribers. Has the exclusive contract prohibition caused these competitive MVPDs to be less willing to invest in programming because they must share their programming investment with their competitors? Would a sunset of the exclusive contract prohibition entice these competitive MVPDs to invest in and launch new programming networks? Do competitive MVPDs have the resources to invest in creating their own video programming? If not, to the extent that certain satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming is withheld from competitive MVPDs, is it likely that non-MVPD-affiliated programming vendors will fill the void by creating competing programming to license to competitive MVPDs, thereby leading to even greater diversity in the video programming market? Are there certain categories of programming that cannot be replicated by either competitive MVPDs or non-MVPD-

        affiliated programming vendors? In the 2010 Program Access Order, the Commission stated:

        If particular programming is replicable, our policies should encourage MVPDs or others to create competing programming, rather than relying on the efforts of others, thereby encouraging investment and innovation in programming and adding to the diversity of programming in the marketplace. Conversely, when programming is non-replicable and valuable to consumers, such as regional sports programming, no amount of investment can duplicate the unique attributes of such programming, and denial of access to such programming can significantly hinder an MVPD from competing in the marketplace.\17\

        \17\ See Review of the Commission's Program Access Rules and Examination of Programming Tying Arrangements, First Report and Order, 25 FCC Rcd 746, 750-51, para. 9 (2010) (``2010 Program Access Order''), affirmed in part and vacated in part sub nom. Cablevision Sys. Corp. et al. v. FCC, 649 F.3d 695 (D.C. Cir. 2011) (``Cablevision II'').

        While the Commission found that RSNs are non-replicable, it concluded that local news and local community or educational programming is ``readily replicable programming.'' We seek comment on how the distinction between replicable and non-replicable content should impact our review of the exclusive contract prohibition.

        Page 24313

        4. Alternatives to Retaining the Exclusive Contract Prohibition as It Exists Today

        46. As discussed in further detail below, to the extent the data do not support retaining the exclusive contract prohibition as it exists today, we seek comment on whether we can nonetheless preserve and protect competition in the video distribution market either by (i) sunsetting the prohibition in its entirety and relying solely on existing protections provided by the program access rules that will not sunset; or (ii) relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition, such as through removal of the prohibition on a market-by-market basis based on the extent of competition in the market or by retaining the prohibition only for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming.

      7. Sunsetting the Exclusive Contract Prohibition in Its Entirety and Relying Solely on Existing Protections

        47. As discussed above, the exclusive contract prohibition is just one of several protections that the program access rules afford to competitive MVPDs in their efforts to compete in the video distribution market. Even if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), these other existing protections will remain in effect. We seek comment on whether these existing protections are sufficient to preserve and protect competition in the video distribution market if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset and whether any additional safeguards should be adopted.

        (i) Section 628(b) Complaints

        48. The Act and the Commission's existing rules allow for the filing of complaints alleging a violation of Section 628(b) of the Act and Section 76.1001(a) of the Commission's rules. These provisions require a complainant to establish three elements in order to demonstrate a violation: (i) The defendant is one of the three entities covered by these provisions (i.e., a cable operator, a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, or a satellite broadcast programming vendor); (ii) the defendant has engaged in an ``unfair act''; and (iii) the ``purpose or effect'' of the unfair act is to ``significantly hinder or prevent'' an MVPD from providing satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming to subscribers or consumers. Even if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), an MVPD would still have the option to file a complaint with the Commission alleging that an exclusive contract between a cable operator and a satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming violates these provisions. We note that the Commission currently considers allegedly ``unfair acts'' involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated programming on a case-by-case basis pursuant to Section 628(b) of the Act and Section 76.1001(a) of the Commission's rules. Applying these provisions, the Commission recently found that the withholding of terrestrially delivered, cable-

        affiliated RSNs from certain MVPDs in the New York, Buffalo, and Hartford/New Haven DMAs violated these provisions. We seek comment regarding whether there are any justifications for applying different rules and procedures to satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming than those that apply to terrestrially delivered, cable-

        affiliated programming.

        49. The Commission previously concluded that Section 628(b) was not an adequate substitute for the prohibition on exclusive contracts under Section 628(c)(2)(D). Among other things, the Commission noted that Section 628(b) ``carries with it an added burden'' to demonstrate that the ``purpose or effect'' of the ``unfair act'' is to ``significantly hinder or prevent'' an MVPD from providing programming. We seek comment on the costs and benefits of moving from a broad, prophylactic prohibition on exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming to reliance instead on a case-by-case process, including Section 628(b) complaints. To what extent would a case-by-case process be more costly for competitive MVPDs than the current prohibition on exclusive contracts? What would be the benefits of eliminating the prohibition on exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming? Would these benefits outweigh the costs of a case-by-case process?

        (a) Case-by-Case Complaint Process

        50. We note that a case-by-case complaint process alleging a violation of Section 628(b) would differ from the current prohibition on exclusive contracts in Section 628(c)(2)(D) in several important respects. First, under the current exclusive contract prohibition, all exclusive contracts between a cable operator and a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer pertaining to satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programming are considered categorically ``unfair.'' If the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), however, exclusive contracts would no longer always be presumed ``unfair.'' Rather, a complainant would have the burden to establish that the exclusive contract at issue is ``unfair'' based on the facts and circumstances presented. Second, under the current exclusive contract prohibition, all exclusive contracts between a cable operator and a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer pertaining to satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming are presumed to harm competition, and competitive MVPDs alleging a prohibited exclusive contract are not required to demonstrate harm. In alleging that an exclusive contract violates Section 628(b), however, a complainant would have the burden of proving that the exclusive contract has the ``purpose or effect'' of ``significantly hindering or preventing'' the MVPD from providing satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming. Third, the current exclusive contract prohibition forbids all exclusive contracts between a cable operator and a satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer pertaining to satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programming, unless a cable operator or programmer can satisfy its burden of demonstrating that an exclusive contract serves the public interest based on the factors set forth in Section 628(c)(4) of the Act and Section 76.1002(c)(4) of the Commission's rules. If the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), however, the situation would be reversed. That is, such exclusive contracts would be permitted, unless an MVPD could carry its burden of demonstrating that the exclusive contract violates Section 628(b) (or, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B)). We seek comment on the above interpretations of Section 628(b) as it pertains to exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programming, particularly the practical implications for competitive MVPDs, cable operators, and satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programmers.

        (b) Extending Rules and Policies Adopted for Section 628(b) Complaints Involving Terrestrially Delivered, Cable-Affiliated Programming to Section 628(b) Complaints Challenging Exclusive Contracts Involving Satellite-Delivered, Cable-Affiliated Programming

        51. The Commission in the 2010 Program Access Order adopted a case-

        by-case complaint process to address unfair acts involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated programming

        Page 24314

        that allegedly violate Section 628(b). In doing so, the Commission adopted rules and policies that would appear to be equally appropriate for complaints alleging that an exclusive contract involving satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programming violates Section 628(b). Accordingly, if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), we propose to apply these same rules and policies to such complaints.

        52. First, the Commission declined to adopt specific evidentiary requirements with respect to proof that the defendant's alleged activities violated Section 628(b). Among other things, the Commission explained that the evidence required to satisfy this burden will vary based on the facts and circumstances of each case and may depend on, among other things, whether the complainant is a new entrant or an established competitor and whether the programming the complainant seeks to access is new or existing programming. In addition, the Commission provided the following illustrative examples of evidence that litigants might consider providing: (i) An appropriately crafted regression analysis that estimates what the complainant's market share in the MVPD market would be if it had access to the programming and how that compares to its actual market share; or (ii) statistically reliable survey data indicating the likelihood that customers would choose not to subscribe to or not to switch to an MVPD that did not carry the withheld programming. The Commission also explained that the discovery process will enable parties to obtain additional evidence. If the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), we propose to apply the same requirements to complaints alleging that an exclusive contract involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming violates Section 628(b).

        53. Second, the Commission found that one category of programming, RSNs, was shown by both Commission precedent and record evidence to be very likely to be both non-replicable and highly valued by consumers. Rather than requiring litigants and the Commission staff to undertake repetitive examinations of this RSN precedent and the relevant historical evidence, the Commission instead allowed complainants to invoke a rebuttable presumption that an ``unfair act'' involving a terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated RSN has the purpose or effect set forth in Section 628(b). The D.C. Circuit upheld the Commission's decision to establish a rebuttable presumption of ``significant hindrance'' for ``unfair acts'' involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs under both First Amendment and Administrative Procedure Act (``APA'') review. Accordingly, to the extent the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially) and we do not retain an exclusive contract prohibition for satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs, should we similarly adopt a rebuttable presumption of ``significant hindrance'' under Section 628(b) for exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated RSNs? If so, we propose to define the term ``RSN'' in the same way the Commission defined that term in the 2010 Program Access Order. Is there any basis to have a rebuttable presumption of ``significant hindrance'' for terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs, but not when these networks are satellite-delivered? Are there any other categories of satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming that can be deemed ``must have'' and for which we should establish a rebuttable presumption of ``significant hindrance''? We note that the Commission in the Comcast-NBCU Order concluded that ``certain national cable programming networks produce programming that is more widely viewed and commands higher advertising revenue than certain broadcast or RSN programming.'' Are there other types of satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming besides RSNs that have no good substitutes, are important for competition, and are non-

        replicable, as the Commission has found with respect to RSNs? To the extent that commenters contend that there are, we ask that they provide reliable, empirical data supporting their positions, rather than merely labeling such programming as ``must have.'' In addition, we request commenters to provide a rational and workable definition of such programming that can be applied objectively.

        54. Third, the Commission concluded that HD programming is growing in significance to consumers and that consumers do not consider the SD version of a particular channel to be an adequate substitute for the HD version due to the different technical characteristics and sometimes different content. Accordingly, the Commission determined that it would analyze the HD version of a network separately from the SD version of similar content for purposes of determining whether an ``unfair act'' has the purpose or effect set forth in Section 628(b). Thus, the fact that a respondent provides the SD version of a network to the complainant will not alone be sufficient to refute the complainant's showing that lack of access to the HD version has the purpose or effect set forth in Section 628(b). Similarly, in cases involving an RSN, withholding the HD feed is rebuttably presumed to cause ``significant hindrance'' even if an SD version of the network is made available to competitors. The D.C. Circuit upheld the Commission's decision on this issue under both First Amendment and APA review. To the extent the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), we believe the same requirements should apply to complaints alleging that an exclusive contract involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming violates Section 628(b). We seek comment on this proposal.

        (c) Additional Rules for Complaints Challenging Exclusive Contracts Involving Satellite-Delivered, Cable-Affiliated Programming

        55. To the extent the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), we seek comment on ways to reduce burdens on both complainants and defendants in connection with complaints alleging that an exclusive contract involving satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programming violates Section 628(b) (or, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B)). We acknowledge that a case-by-case complaint process for addressing exclusive contracts involving satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated, national programming networks may impose some burdens for litigants and the Commission, especially in comparison to the current broad, prophylactic prohibition. For example, although several MVPDs could join as complainants, the showing in the complaint and any subsequent ruling on the complaint (either grant or denial) will be limited to the complainants. Other competitive MVPDs that are not parties to the complaint would have to file their own complaint and demonstrate how the exclusive contract at issue is ``unfair'' and has ``significantly hindered'' them from providing programming. Given the number of competitive MVPDs nationwide that might seek access to a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated, national programming network that is subject to an exclusive contract with cable operators, the number of such complaints involving just one national network could be significant.

        56. We seek comment on how to reduce these potential burdens for both complainants and defendants. For example, rather than requiring litigants and the Commission staff to undertake

        Page 24315

        repetitive examinations of the same network, we seek comment on whether the Commission could establish a rebuttable presumption that, once a complainant succeeds in demonstrating that an exclusive contract involving a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming network violates Section 628(b) (or, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B)), any other exclusive contract involving the same network violates Section 628(b) (or Section 628(c)(2)(B)). We seek comment on whether adoption of such a rebuttable presumption is rational. For example, in the event the Commission finds that an exclusive contract violates Section 628(b) (or Section 628(c)(2)(B)) in response to a complaint brought by a small, fledgling MVPD, is it rational to assume that the Commission is likely to reach the same conclusion when the complaint is brought by a large, established MVPD?

        57. We also seek comment on whether there would be any benefit to retaining post-sunset our existing process whereby a cable operator or a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer may file a Petition for Exclusivity seeking Commission approval for an exclusive contract involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming by demonstrating that the arrangement serves the public interest based on the factors set forth in Section 628(c)(4) of the Act and Section 76.1002(c)(4) of the Commission's rules. While a cable operator post-

        sunset would be permitted generally to enter into an exclusive contract with a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming network without receiving prior Commission approval, we propose that the grant of a Petition for Exclusivity would immunize such an exclusive contract from potential complaints alleging a violation of Section 628(b), as well as Section 628(c)(2)(B). We further propose that, to the extent we were to deny a Petition for Exclusivity post-sunset, the petitioner would not be precluded from entering into or enforcing the exclusive contract subject to the petition. Rather, denial of a Petition for Exclusivity post-sunset would mean that the exclusive contract at issue may not be permissible in all cases if challenged pursuant to Section 628(b) or, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B). We seek comment on the costs and benefits of retaining this petition process after a sunset, especially whether the burdens for the Commission staff and impacted parties would outweigh any benefits. We also seek comment on any other ways to reduce the potential burdens for both complainants and defendants resulting from a case-by-case complaint process.

        (ii) Section 628(c)(2)(B) Discrimination Complaints

        58. We believe that discrimination complaints under Section 628(c)(2)(B) also will provide some protection for competitive MVPDs should the exclusive contract prohibition sunset (wholly or partially). Discrimination can take two forms: price discrimination and non-price discrimination. Non-price discrimination includes an unreasonable refusal to license programming to an MVPD. A refusal to license is permissible only if there is a ``legitimate business justification'' for the conduct. As discussed below, a refusal to license can take two forms. First, a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer may refuse to license its programming to all MVPDs in a market except for one (such as its affiliated cable operator), thereby providing the affiliated cable operator with exclusive access to the programming. Second, a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer may selectively refuse to license its programming to certain MVPDs in a market (such as a recent entrant) while licensing the programming to other MVPDs (such as its affiliated cable operator and DBS operators). We seek comment on each of these scenarios below.

        (a) Challenging an Exclusive Arrangement as an Unreasonable Refusal to License

        59. We seek comment on the interplay between the potential sunset of the exclusive contact prohibition in Section 628(c)(2)(D) and the continued prohibition on unreasonable refusals to license pursuant to Section 628(c)(2)(B). As an initial matter, we note that Section 628(c)(2)(D) prohibits ``exclusive contracts * * * between a cable operator and a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest.'' This language presumes that an agreement will exist between the cable operator and the satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer that would provide the cable operator with exclusivity. In the event that a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer unilaterally refuses to license its programming to all MVPDs in a market except for one cable operator and without any exclusive contract with the cable operator, we believe an MVPD can challenge this conduct as an unreasonable refusal to license in violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B). While a cable operator would be permitted generally to enter into an exclusive contract with the satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer in the event of a sunset, the scenario presented here does not involve an exclusive contract; rather, it involves unilateral action by the satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer. We seek comment on this interpretation. In defending against a complaint, the satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer would be required to provide a ``legitimate business justification'' for its conduct.

        60. In the event that a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer and a cable operator enter into an exclusive contract post-

        sunset (complete or partial), we seek comment on whether an MVPD can challenge this exclusive contract as an unreasonable refusal to license in violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B).\18\ We believe that there are legitimate arguments for and against this interpretation. We seek comment on which of the interpretations set forth below is more reasonable and consistent with the goals of Section 628.

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

        \18\ To the extent that we determine that an MVPD can challenge an exclusive contract as an unreasonable refusal to license in violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B) post-sunset, we seek comment above on ways to reduce the potential burdens for both complainants and defendants resulting from a case-by-case complaint process. See supra paras. 56-57.

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

        61. In favor of interpreting Section 628(c)(2)(B) to allow a challenge post-sunset to an exclusive contract as an unreasonable refusal to license, we note that Section 628(c)(2)(B)(iv) provides that it is not a violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B) for a satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer to ``enter into an exclusive contract that is permitted under Section 628(c)(2)(D).'' The Commission has previously interpreted this language to pertain to only those exclusive contracts that have been deemed by the Commission to be in the public interest pursuant to the factors set forth in Section 628(c)(4). This provision is silent regarding exclusive contracts that are generally permissible after a sunset pursuant to Section 628(c)(5). Does the omission of post-sunset exclusive contracts from both Section 628(c)(2)(D) and Section 628(c)(2)(B)(iv) mean that Congress intended that such contracts might still be challenged as impermissibly discriminatory in violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B)? In addition, we note that the exclusive contract prohibition in Section 628(c)(2)(D) applies to exclusive contracts between a satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programmer and a cable operator; it does not apply to exclusive contracts between a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer and a DBS

        Page 24316

        operator. Both before and after a sunset, however, the decision of a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer to license its programming to a DBS operator but not to other MVPDs might be challenged as an unreasonable refusal to license pursuant to Section 628(c)(2)(B). If, post-sunset, an MVPD cannot challenge an exclusive arrangement between a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer and a cable operator as an unreasonable refusal to license in violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B), would this produce an anomalous result? Specifically, in challenging an exclusive contract between a satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer and a cable operator, an MVPD would have to rely on Section 628(b), which places the burden on the MVPD to demonstrate that the defendant has engaged in an ``unfair act'' that has the ``purpose or effect'' of ``significantly hindering or preventing'' the MVPD from providing satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming to subscribers or consumers. By contrast, in challenging an exclusive contract between a satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer and a DBS operator, an MVPD could rely on Section 628(c)(2)(B), which presumes harm in every case and places the burden on the satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer to provide a ``legitimate business justification'' for its conduct. Is there any basis for placing a greater burden on an MVPD in challenging an exclusive contract between a satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programmer and a cable operator than between a satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer and a DBS operator?

        62. On the other hand, we note that there are legitimate arguments against interpreting Section 628(c)(2)(B) to allow an MVPD to challenge an exclusive contract between a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer and a cable operator post-sunset as an unreasonable refusal to license. Currently, with the exclusive contract prohibition in effect, an exclusive contract between a satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programmer and a cable operator is prohibited, unless the programmer or cable operator can demonstrate that the exclusive contract serves the public interest based on the factors set forth in Section 628(c)(4). If, post-sunset, an MVPD can challenge an exclusive contract between a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer and a cable operator as an unreasonable refusal to license in violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B), the satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer would be required to demonstrate a ``legitimate business reason'' for its conduct. Is it reasonable to interpret Section 628 to provide that, post-sunset, the public interest factors in Section 628(c)(4) would be replaced with a showing of a ``legitimate business reason'' in response to a complaint alleging a violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B)? We note that two of the public interest factors in Section 628(c)(4) focus on competition in the video distribution market, allowing a proponent of exclusivity to demonstrate how the exclusive contract will not adversely impact competition. In a complaint alleging discrimination under Section 628(c)(2)(B), however, the alleged discriminatory act is presumed to harm competition in every case. Is it reasonable to interpret Section 628 to provide that, pre-

        sunset, a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer or a cable operator could make a showing that an exclusive contract would not adversely impact competition pursuant to the public interest factors in Section 628(c)(4), but, post-sunset, exclusivity is presumed to harm competition in every case when challenged pursuant to Section 628(c)(2)(B)?

        63. In addition to the foregoing, we seek comment on whether the legislative history of the 1992 Cable Act supports either of the above interpretations. The Senate Report accompanying the 1992 Cable Act states that the ``bill does not equate exclusivity with an unreasonable refusal to deal.'' This statement might be read to imply that Congress considered exclusive contracts and unreasonable refusals to deal to be mutually exclusive, with the effect that once a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer enters into an exclusive contract with a cable operator post-sunset, the contract cannot be challenged as an unreasonable refusal to license pursuant to Section 628(c)(2)(B). Another part of the Senate Report, however, states that ``the dominance in the market of the distributor obtaining exclusivity should be considered in determining whether an exclusive arrangement amounts to an unreasonable refusal to deal.'' This statement might be read to imply that Congress did not consider exclusive contracts and unreasonable refusals to license to be mutually exclusive, with the effect that an exclusive contract could be challenged as an unreasonable refusal to license pursuant to Section 628(c)(2)(B).

        (b) Selective Refusals To License Programming

        64. Notwithstanding the question raised in the previous section of whether an MVPD can challenge post-sunset an exclusive arrangement between a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer and a cable operator as an unreasonable refusal to license in violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B), our rules and precedent establish that the discrimination provision in Section 628(c)(2)(B) would prevent a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer from licensing its content to MVPD A (such as a DBS operator) in a given market area, but to selectively refuse to license the content to MVPD B (such as a telco video provider) in the same area, absent a legitimate business reason. When a satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer discriminates among MVPDs in this manner, it faces the prospect of a complaint alleging non-price discrimination in violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B). As noted above, complaints alleging a violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B) do not require a showing of harm to the complainant.

        65. We seek comment on whether the right of an MVPD to challenge a selective refusal to license as a form of prohibited non-price discrimination under Section 628(c)(2)(B) will help to preserve and protect competition in the video distribution market if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially). As reflected in Appendix A, the two DBS operators together have approximately 34 percent of MVPD subscribers nationwide today. Because a national programming network that refuses to license its content to these MVPDs will forgo significant licensing fees and advertising revenues, is it reasonable to assume that most satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated, national programming networks will license their content to DBS operators? If they do, we interpret Section 628(c)(2)(B) as permitting other competitive MVPDs, such as a telco video provider, to bring non-

        price discrimination complaints should these programmers refuse to deal with them. How does this analysis change with respect to local and regional markets, where cable operators may have an overwhelming share of the market or a vertically integrated cable operator may pass a large percentage of television households?

        66. The Commission previously concluded that the discrimination provision in Section 628(c)(2)(B) is not an adequate substitute for the prohibition on exclusive contracts

        Page 24317

        under Section 628(c)(2)(D). Among other things, the Commission noted that a non-price discrimination complaint requires an MVPD to demonstrate that the conduct was ``unreasonable,'' which the Commission noted may be difficult to establish. We seek comment on the costs and benefits of moving from a broad, prophylactic prohibition on exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming to reliance instead on a case-by-case process, including non-price discrimination complaints.

        (iii) Section 628(c)(2)(A) Undue Influence Complaints

        67. We seek comment on the extent to which undue influence complaints under Section 628(c)(2)(A) may also provide some protection for competitive MVPDs should the exclusive contract prohibition sunset (wholly or partially). Section 628(c)(2)(A) precludes a cable operator that has an attributable interest in a satellite cable programming vendor or a satellite broadcast programming vendor from ``unduly or improperly influencing the decision of such vendor to sell, or the prices, terms, and conditions of sale of, satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming to any unaffiliated MVPD.'' The Commission has explained that the ``concept of undue influence between affiliated firms is closely linked with discriminatory practices and exclusive contracting'' and that the prohibition on undue influence ``can play a supporting role where information is available (such as might come from an internal `whistleblower') that evidences `undue influence' between affiliated firms to initiate or maintain anticompetitive discriminatory pricing, contracting, or product withholding.'' The Commission acknowledged that ``such conduct may be difficult for the Commission or complainants to establish'' but ``its regulation provides a useful support for direct discrimination and contracting regulation.'' To what extent, if any, will the prohibition on undue influence provide some protection for competitive MVPDs should the exclusive contract prohibition sunset? If the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset, then a cable operator would be permitted generally to enter into an exclusive contract with a satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programming network, although the contract may be deemed to violate Section 628(b) (or, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B)) after the conclusion of a complaint proceeding. In the event the exclusive contract prohibition sunsets, if a cable operator ``unduly influences'' a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer to enter into an exclusive contract, would that conduct violate Section 628(c)(2)(A) even though the underlying contract would be permissible (absent a finding of a violation of Section 628(b) (or, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B)))? Stated differently, in the event of a sunset, can a cable operator ``unduly influence'' a satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer to enter into an exclusive contract only if the underlying contract violates Section 628(b) (or, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B))?

      8. Relaxing the Exclusive Contract Prohibition

        68. Rather than sunsetting the exclusive contract prohibition in its entirety and relying solely on existing protections provided by the program access rules that will not sunset, we seek comment on whether we should instead relax, rather than sunset, the exclusivity prohibition in the ways discussed below, or in some other way. We ask parties to comment on whether retaining the exclusivity ban in certain circumstances would be more effective in preserving and protecting competition in the video distribution market than permitting the exclusive contract prohibition to sunset entirely. In addition to the proposals below, we invite comment on other ways to relax the exclusive contract prohibition.

        (i) Sunsetting the Exclusive Contract Prohibition on a Market-by-Market Basis

        69. We seek comment on whether to establish a process whereby a cable operator or satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer can file a Petition for Sunset seeking to remove the exclusive contract prohibition on a market-by-market basis based on the extent of competition in the market.\19\ In the 2002 Extension Order, the Commission explained that ``clustering, accompanied by an increase in vertically integrated regional programming networks affiliated with cable MSOs that control system clusters, will increase the incentive of cable operators to practice anticompetitive foreclosure of access to vertically integrated programming.'' Moreover, as noted above, the market share held by cable operators in DMAs varies considerably, from a high in the 80 percent range to a low in the 20 percent range. As the Commission has explained previously, particularly ``where competitive MVPDs are limited in their market share, a cable-affiliated programmer will be able to recoup a substantial amount, if not all, of the revenues foregone by pursuing a withholding strategy.'' Moreover, in the 2007 Extension Order, the Commission provided an empirical analysis demonstrating that the profitability of withholding increases as the number of television households passed by a vertically integrated cable operator increases in a given market area, such as through clustering. Accordingly, a cable-affiliated programmer will have an increased incentive to enter into exclusive contracts with cable operators in those areas where the market share of competitive MVPDs is comparatively low or where its affiliated cable operator passes a large percentage of television households or where both circumstances are present. If there was not a blanket prohibition on exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming, would incumbent cable operators and cable-affiliated programmers enter into exclusive contracts in these markets? If so, does the wide variation in cable market share and television households passed by a vertically integrated cable operator on a regional and local basis call for a more granular assessment of the continued need for an exclusive contract prohibition in individual markets, rather than a broad rule that applies to all markets equally? Would such a market-by-market assessment necessarily be based on a Commission finding that satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programming remains necessary for competition in the video distribution market? That is, absent such a finding, would a market-by-market assessment approach mean that the exclusive contract prohibition would sunset only in areas where satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers lack an incentive to enter into exclusive contracts, regardless of the importance of the programming at issue for competition? Is there any basis for interpreting the sunset provision in Section 628(c)(5) in this manner, which might permit exclusive contracts only when there is little possibility such contracts will exist?

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

        \19\ We note that the Commission sought comment on a similar proposal in the 2007 Program Access NPRM. See Review of the Commission's Program Access Rules and Examination of Programming Tying Arrangements, MB Docket No. 07-198, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 22 FCC Rcd 17791, 17859, para. 114 (2007) (seeking comment on whether the Commission can establish a procedure that would shorten the term of the exclusive contract prohibition if, after two years (i.e., October 5, 2009), a cable operator can show competition from new entrant MVPDs has reached a certain penetration level in the DMA) (``2007 Program Access NPRM''). We hereby incorporate by reference the comments filed in response to this proposal.

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

        70. To the extent we establish a process whereby a cable operator or

        Page 24318

        satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer can petition to remove the exclusive contract prohibition on a market-by-market basis, we seek comment on the details of this process. First, in assessing whether to sunset the exclusive contract prohibition in an individual market, we propose to apply the same test set forth in Section 628(c)(5)--i.e., whether the prohibition ``continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.'' Who should bear the burdens of production and persuasion in demonstrating that the exclusive contract prohibition either does or does not meet this test in an individual market? While a petitioner (in this case, the cable operator or satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer) might normally bear these burdens, Congress established that the exclusive contract prohibition would sunset unless it continues to be necessary pursuant to this test. The Commission has explained that Section 628(c)(5) thus ``creates a presumption that the rule will sunset'' unless it continues to be necessary. Does this call for a regime where, in response to a petition seeking to remove the prohibition in an individual market, the burden of production shifts to competitive MVPDs and other interested parties to put forth evidence demonstrating that the prohibition continues to be necessary? To provide guidance to impacted parties, should we establish a specific benchmark which, if met, would establish a rebuttable presumption that the market is not sufficiently competitive to allow the exclusive contract prohibition to sunset? For example, should the market be rebuttably presumed to not be sufficiently competitive to allow the exclusive contract prohibition to sunset if the market share held by competitive MVPDs is below a certain threshold or television households passed by a vertically integrated cable operator is above a certain threshold? We ask commenters to provide support for any proposed threshold. Should we instead apply the test set forth in Section 628(c)(5) on an entirely case-by-case basis, considering all of the facts and circumstances presented, without establishing a specific benchmark? Second, how should we define the ``market'' for purposes of these petitions? Should we establish a specific market size for purpose of the petitions (such as DMA, county, or franchise area) or should we allow petitioners to seek a sunset of the exclusive contract prohibition for any size market they choose? Third, we seek comment on procedural deadlines. Given the likely fact-intensive nature of these petitions, we propose to establish a pleading cycle that is identical to the one established for complaints involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated programming. Specifically, we propose to establish a 45-day opposition period and a 15-day reply period. Fourth, to the extent that the exclusive contract prohibition has not been removed in an individual market, we propose to retain our existing rules and procedures whereby a cable operator or a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer can seek prior Commission approval to enter into an exclusive contract by demonstrating that the arrangement satisfies the factors set forth in Section 628(c)(4) of the Act and Section 76.1002(c)(4) of the Commission's rules. Fifth, we seek comment on whether to adopt a sunset date for the exclusive contract prohibition, thereby eliminating the need for further market-based petitions, subject to a review by the Commission in the year prior to the sunset date. Should the sunset date be five years from the current sunset date (i.e., until October 5, 2017), consistent with the two prior five-year extensions?

        71. We also seek comment on the practical effect of sunsetting the exclusive contract prohibition on a market-by-market basis. For example, to the extent that certain competitive MVPDs, such as DBS providers, market their service on a nationwide basis, how will the sunset of the exclusive contract prohibition in individual markets impact their marketing efforts? For example, if a certain satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programming network is available to DBS customers in some markets, but not in others due to exclusive contracts with cable operators, how burdensome will it be for DBS providers to inform subscribers and potential customers of the limited availability of this programming and to implement the selective availability of the programming? In addition to this potential concern, we seek comment on the other costs and benefits of moving from a broad, prophylactic prohibition on exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming throughout the nation to reliance instead on a market-by-market assessment.

        (ii) Retaining an Exclusive Contract Prohibition for Satellite-

        Delivered, Cable-Affiliated RSNs and Other Satellite-Delivered, Cable-

        Affiliated ``Must Have'' Programming

        72. We seek comment on whether we should retain an exclusive contract prohibition for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming. The Commission has previously explained that RSNs have no good substitutes, are important for competition, and are non-replicable. Moreover, in his dissenting opinion to the D.C. Circuit decision affirming the 2007 Extension Order, Judge Kavanaugh articulated the following explanation for why a ban on exclusive contracts for RSNs may be appropriate:

        I would leave open the possibility that the Government might still impose a prospective ban on some exclusive agreements between video programming distributors and affiliated regional video programming networks, particularly regional sports networks. That is because the upstream market in which video programming distributors contract with regional networks is less competitive than the national market * * *. Market share and other relevant factors in certain areas may dictate tolerance of a narrow exclusivity ban. Situations where a highly desirable ``must have'' regional sports network is controlled by one video programming distributor might justify a targeted restraint on such regional exclusivity arrangements. I need not definitively address such a possibility in this case.

        73. We note, however, that the Commission in the 2010 Program Access Order declined to adopt a flat ban on exclusive contracts involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs pursuant to Section 628(b) of the Act. Noting empirical evidence that withholding of an RSN in one case did not have an impact on competition, the Commission declined to adopt a general conclusion regarding RSNs, adopting instead a case-by-case approach, albeit with a rebuttable presumption that an ``unfair act'' involving a terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated RSN has the purpose or effect set forth in Section 628(b). The Commission explained that ``case-by-case consideration of the impact on competition in the video distribution market is necessary to address whether unfair practices significantly hinder competition in particular cases.''

        74. Are there legal and/or policy reasons why the Commission may want to establish a case-by-case approach for assessing exclusive contracts involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs, but to retain an across-the-board prohibition on exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs? We note that, in adopting a case-by-case approach for terrestrially delivered, cable-

        affiliated RSNs, the Commission was applying and interpreting Section 628(b) of the Act, which prohibits ``unfair acts'' that have the ``purpose or effect'' to ``significantly hinder or prevent'' an

        Page 24319

        MVPD from providing satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming to subscribers or consumers. In considering a sunset of the exclusive contract prohibition, however, we are applying and interpreting Section 628(c)(5) of the Act, which requires the Commission to determine whether the exclusive contract prohibition ``continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.'' Unlike Section 628(b), the language in Section 628(c)(5) does not require the Commission to assess whether particular exclusive contracts are ``unfair'' or whether they have the ``purpose or effect'' to ``significantly hinder or prevent'' an MVPD from providing satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming to subscribers or consumers. We note that two vertically integrated cable operators, Comcast and Cablevision, previously stated before the D.C. Circuit that a partial sunset of the exclusive contract prohibition is a legally permissible approach, explaining that ``Section 628(c)(5) grants the FCC additional sunsetting authority, and nothing in the statute suggests that the FCC must do so on an all-or-nothing basis.'' Does this difference in statutory language provide a basis for treating satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs differently from terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs? In addition, are there policy reasons why the Commission may want to retain the exclusivity ban as it applies to satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs? If so, we propose to define the term ``RSN'' in the same way the Commission defined that term in the 2010 Program Access Order.

        75. To the extent we retain an exclusive contract prohibition for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs, we propose to retain our existing rules and procedures whereby a cable operator or a satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programmer can file a Petition for Exclusivity seeking prior Commission approval to enter into an exclusive contract by demonstrating that the arrangement satisfies the factors set forth in Section 628(c)(4) of the Act and Section 76.1002(c)(4) of the Commission's rules. We seek comment on whether this process is sufficient for addressing those instances where an exclusive contract pertaining to a satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated RSN might serve the public interest. We note that, if we were to retain an exclusive contract prohibition for only satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs, our rules would apply burdens to different parties depending on whether or not the programming subject to an exclusive contract is an RSN: (i) In the case of satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs, exclusive contracts with cable operators would be generally prohibited, unless a cable operator or RSN can satisfy its burden of demonstrating that an exclusive contract serves the public interest based on the factors set forth in Section 628(c)(4) of the Act and Section 76.1002(c)(4) of the Commission's rules; and (ii) in the case of all other satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programming, exclusive contracts with cable operators would be generally permitted, unless an MVPD can satisfy its burden of demonstrating that the exclusive contract violates Section 628(b) of the Act and Section 76.1001(a) of the Commission's rules (or, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Act and Section 76.1002(b) of the Commission's rules). Given the Commission precedent and relevant historical evidence pertaining to the importance of RSNs for competition, as well as their non-substitutability and non-

        replicability, we believe there is a sufficient basis for drawing this distinction between RSN and non-RSN programming. We seek comment on this view.

        76. Are there any other categories of satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programming besides RSNs that can be deemed ``must have'' and for which we should retain the exclusivity prohibition? We note that the Commission in the Comcast-NBCU Order concluded that ``certain national cable programming networks produce programming that is more widely viewed and commands higher advertising revenue than certain broadcast or RSN programming.'' Are there other types of satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programming besides RSNs that have no good substitutes, are important for competition, and are non-replicable, as the Commission has found with respect to RSNs? To the extent that commenters contend that there are, we ask that they provide reliable, empirical data supporting their positions, rather than merely labeling such programming as ``must have.'' In addition, we request commenters to provide a rational and workable definition of such programming that can be applied objectively. We note that in the 2007 Extension Order the Commission declined to differentiate between categories of programming for purposes of the exclusive contract prohibition for a number of legal and policy reasons.\20\ We seek comment on whether any of the concerns the Commission expressed in the 2007 Extension Order should prevent us from retaining an exclusive contract prohibition for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs, or potentially other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming, given the state of the market today.

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

        \20\ These reasons were as follows: (i) Congress did not distinguish between different types of satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programming in adopting the exclusive contract prohibition in Section 628(c)(2)(D) (see 2007 Extension Order, 22 FCC Rcd at 17839-40, para. 69; see also 2002 Extension Order, 17 FCC Rcd at 12156, para. 69); (ii) requests to relieve satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programming networks from the exclusive contract prohibition can be addressed through individual exclusivity petitions satisfying the factors set forth in Section 628(c)(4) (see 2007 Extension Order, 22 FCC Rcd at 17839-40, para. 69); (iii) no commenter provided a rational and workable definition of ``must have'' programming that would allow the Commission to apply the exclusive contract prohibition to only this type of programming (see id.); (iv) the difficulty of developing an objective process of general applicability to determine what programming may or may not be essential to preserve and protect competition (see id.; see also 2002 Extension Order, 17 FCC Rcd at 12156, para. 69); and (v) distinguishing between different types of satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming might raise First Amendment concerns (see 2007 Extension Order, 22 FCC Rcd at 17839-40, para. 69; see also 2002 Extension Order, 17 FCC Rcd at 12156, para. 69).

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

        77. With respect to First Amendment concerns, we note that the Commission in the 2010 Program Access Order applied a rebuttable presumption of significant hindrance to one category of programming--

        terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs. The D.C. Circuit rejected claims that this was a content-based restriction on speech subject to strict scrutiny, explaining that:

        There is absolutely no evidence, nor even any serious suggestion, that the Commission issued its regulations to disfavor certain messages or ideas. The clear and undisputed evidence shows that the Commission established presumptions for RSN programming due to that programming's economic characteristics, not to its communicative impact. Thus content-neutral, the presumptions are subject only to intermediate scrutiny.

        In applying intermediate scrutiny, the D.C. Circuit ruled that, ``given record evidence demonstrating the significant impact of RSN programming withholding, the Commission's presumptions represent a narrowly tailored effort to further the important governmental interest of increasing competition in video programming.'' Based on the D.C. Circuit's decision, we do not believe that retaining an exclusive contract prohibition for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs

        Page 24320

        and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming would run afoul of the First Amendment. We seek comment on this view.

        78. To the extent we retain an exclusive contract prohibition for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming, we propose to apply the prohibition independently to the SD and HD versions of the same network. As discussed above, the Commission has concluded that HD programming is growing in significance to consumers and that consumers do not consider the SD version of a particular channel to be an adequate substitute for the HD version due to the different technical characteristics and sometimes different content. Accordingly, the Commission has determined that it will analyze the HD version of a network separately from the SD version with similar content for purposes of determining whether an ``unfair act'' has the purpose or effect set forth in Section 628(b). Because this same finding would appear to apply to an exclusive contract prohibition, we propose that, if a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer makes the SD version of an RSN or other ``must have'' programming available to MVPDs, this would not exempt the satellite-delivered, HD version of the RSN or other ``must have'' programming from the exclusive contract prohibition. We seek comment on this view.

        79. To the extent we retain an exclusive contract prohibition pursuant to Section 628(c)(5) only for satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming, should we adopt a date when this prohibition will sunset, subject to a review by the Commission in the year prior to the sunset date? Should the sunset date be five years from the current sunset date (i.e., until October 5, 2017), consistent with the two prior five-year extensions?

        80. Should we combine the two approaches to partial sunsetting of the exclusive contract prohibition, by adopting a market-by-market approach and also retaining the prohibition for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming? If so, how should the two approaches interrelate? If the exclusive contract prohibition sunsets in a specific market, should this sunset also apply to satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming? Or, given the critical nature of RSNs and other ``must have'' programming for competition, should the exclusive contract prohibition for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming continue to apply even if the exclusive contract prohibition sunsets for other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming in the market? Should the Commission instead assess whether the exclusive contract prohibition should continue to apply to satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming on a market-by-market basis, considering all of the facts and circumstances presented in the petition?

        5. Implementation of a Sunset in a Manner That Minimizes Any Potential Disruption for Consumers

        81. Whether we retain, sunset, or relax the exclusive contract prohibition, our goal is protect consumers and minimize any potential disruption. As an initial matter, as noted above, many Comcast-

        affiliated networks are subject to program access conditions adopted in the Comcast/NBCU Order and will continue to be subject to these conditions for six more years (until January 2018, assuming they are not modified earlier in response to a petition). These networks will not be impacted by a sunset (complete or partial). With respect to other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated networks, we seek comment below on how sunsetting the exclusive contract prohibition (wholly or partially) will impact consumers, and whether a phased implementation of a sunset is necessary to minimize any potential disruption to consumers. As discussed above, to the extent the data do not support retaining the exclusive contract prohibition as it exists today, we seek comment above on sunsetting or relaxing the prohibition. To the extent the prohibition sunsets (wholly or partially), we envision that there are at least two possible scenarios with respect to existing affiliation agreements. We seek comment on which scenario is more likely and if there are any other likely scenarios. First, if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset, an existing affiliation agreement between a cable-affiliated programmer and an MVPD pertaining to a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming network might allow the programmer to terminate or modify the existing agreement immediately on the effective date of the sunset and to instead enter into an exclusive contract with a cable operator. Second, even if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset, an existing affiliation agreement might require the satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer to continue to provide the programming to the MVPD for the duration of the term of the affiliation agreement despite the sunset. We seek comment on these alternative scenarios below.

      9. Termination or Modification of Affiliation Agreements on the Effective Date of the Sunset

        82. To the extent that existing affiliation agreements permit satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers to terminate or modify the agreements immediately on the effective date of the sunset and to instead enter into an exclusive contract with a cable operator, is there any basis to expect that many satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programmers would terminate or modify existing agreements simultaneously and thereby cause significant disruption to consumers by depriving them of programming they have come to expect? Are our existing rules sufficient to prevent any customer disruption? For example, to the extent that a cable-affiliated programmer terminates or modifies an existing affiliation agreement with an MVPD pertaining to a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming network and instead enters into an exclusive arrangement with a cable operator, the MVPD could file a complaint alleging a violation of Section 628(b) of the Act (and, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Act). While our program access rules contain specific procedures for the filing of a petition for a standstill along with a program access complaint when seeking to renew an existing affiliation agreement, should our standstill procedures also apply when an MVPD files a program access complaint based on a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer's mid-term termination or modification of an affiliation agreement resulting from the sunset? If the standstill petition is granted, the price, terms, and other conditions of the existing affiliation agreement will remain in place pending resolution of the program access complaint, thereby reducing consumer disruption.

        83. Rather than relying on the complaint and standstill process, should we instead abrogate provisions of affiliation agreements that would allow satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers to terminate or modify their existing agreements with MVPDs immediately on the effective date of the sunset? We seek comment regarding the benefits and burdens of abrogating contractual provisions that otherwise would permit a programmer to terminate or modify its existing agreement with an unaffiliated MVPD

        Page 24321

        immediately upon sunset of the exclusive contract prohibition. We seek comment regarding how the abrogation of such contractual provisions would be congruous with a possible finding to sunset the exclusive contract prohibition. In NCTA v. FCC, the D.C. Circuit upheld the Commission's abrogation of existing contracts in the program access context. Alternatively, to minimize any potential disruption to consumers, should we adopt a phased implementation of the sunset? For example, should we provide that, for a period of three years from the sunset date, a cable-affiliated programmer cannot enter into an exclusive contract with a cable operator for a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming network that is an RSN (assuming the prohibition is not retained for RSNs) or is ranked within the Top 20 cable networks as measured by either prime time ratings, average all-

        day ratings, or total number of subscribers? Should we adopt a similar restriction, for a period of two years from the sunset date, for a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming network that is ranked within the Top 21-50 cable networks? We seek comment on these proposals and any other appropriate ways to minimize any disruption to consumers resulting from the sunset in the event that existing affiliation agreements permit satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers to terminate or modify them on the effective date of the sunset.

      10. Continued Enforcement of Existing Affiliation Agreements Despite the Sunset

        84. To the extent that existing affiliation agreements require cable-affiliated programmers to continue to provide satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated programming networks to MVPDs for the duration of the term of the existing agreement despite the sunset of the exclusive contract prohibition, we seek comment on the interplay between the sunset and the discrimination provision of the program access rules. For example, assume that a cable-affiliated programmer has existing affiliation agreements for a satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated programming network with three MVPDs (including one cable operator) subject to the following termination dates: December 31, 2012 (cable operator); December 31, 2013 (MVPD A); December 31, 2014 (MVPD B). If the satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer enters into an exclusive contract with the cable operator after its current agreement expires on December 31, 2012, would the satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer be required to make the programming available to all MVPDs until after the expiration of the latest-

        expiring affiliation agreement with an MVPD other than the cable operator that is a party to the exclusive contract? We seek comment on whether it would be impermissibly discriminatory in violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B) if the satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer were to refuse to license the network to MVPD A after December 31, 2013, while continuing to provide the programming to MVPD B until its agreement expires on December 31, 2014, based on the future enforcement of an exclusive contract with the cable operator as of January 1, 2015, after the expiration of the agreement with MVPD B. While the satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer's discriminatory treatment of MVPD A relative to MVPD B and the cable operator during the period of December 31, 2013 to December 31, 2014 might be justified based on a legitimate business reason, is the future enforcement of an exclusive contract a legitimate business reason for such discriminatory conduct? If not, then the satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer would not be permitted to have the exclusivity period with the cable operator begin, or to refuse to license the programming to other MVPDs, until all affiliation agreements with other MVPDs expire. Thus, in this scenario, absent a legitimate business reason, the satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer would be required to enter into an affiliation agreement with MVPD A that terminates no earlier than December 31, 2014 (i.e., the expiration of the latest-expiring affiliation agreement with an MVPD other than the cable operator that is a party to the exclusive contract). We seek comment on this view.

        85. To the extent that affiliation agreements require cable-

        affiliated programmers to continue to provide satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming networks to MVPDs for the duration of the term of the existing agreement despite the sunset, does the anti-

        discrimination provision of Section 628(c)(2)(B) as described here prevent the enforcement of any exclusive contract until the expiration of the latest-expiring affiliation agreement with an MVPD other than the cable operator that is a party to the exclusive contract? Will this limit the immediate impact of the sunset (complete or partial) and help to minimize any potential disruption to consumers? What impact, if any, does Section 628(c)(2)(B)(iv) have on this discussion? Even if this section could be read to immunize post-sunset exclusive contracts from being challenged as impermissibly discriminatory in violation of Section 628(c)(2)(B), would this provision allow a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer to selectively refuse to license programming to certain MVPDs based on future enforcement of an exclusive contract, as described here?

        6. First Amendment

        86. We ask commenters to consider carefully how the First Amendment impacts our review of the exclusive contract prohibition, including the proposals to relax the prohibition. As the D.C. Circuit explained in rejecting a facial challenge to the constitutionality of the program access provisions, these provisions will survive intermediate scrutiny if they ``further an important or substantial governmental interest; if the governmental interest is unrelated to the suppression of free expression; and if the incidental restriction on alleged First Amendment freedoms is no greater than is essential to the furtherance of that interest.'' Given the current state of competition in the video programming market and the video distribution market, does the First Amendment require the exclusive contract prohibition as it exists today to sunset or to be relaxed? Is a prohibition on all exclusive contracts in all markets between cable operators and cable-affiliated programmers pertaining to satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming ``no greater than is essential'' to the furtherance of the substantial government interest in promoting competition in the MVPD market? Would retaining the prohibition only for satellite-delivered, cable-

        affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming, and/or allowing the prohibition to sunset on a market-by-market basis, be a sufficiently tailored approach?

        87. We note that, in rejecting a facial First Amendment challenge to the 2010 Program Access Order in which the Commission adopted a case-by-case approach for considering unfair acts involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated programming, the D.C. Circuit explained that, ``by imposing liability only when complainants demonstrate that a company's unfair act has `the purpose or effect' of `hindering significantly or * * * preventing' the provision of satellite programming, * * * the Commission's terrestrial programming rules specifically target activities where the governmental interest is greatest.'' Moreover, the D.C.

        Page 24322

        Circuit stated that the Commission, in adopting this case-by-case approach, ``has no obligation to establish that vertically integrated cable companies retain a stranglehold on competition nationally or that all withholding of terrestrially delivered programming negatively affects competition.'' Is a case-by-case approach pursuant to Section 628(b) (and, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B)) or a narrowed application of the exclusive contract prohibition as discussed above, rather than the current broad, prophylactic prohibition, preferable under the First Amendment given the competitive environment today? We also seek comment on the First Amendment implications of a phased implementation of a sunset as discussed above to minimize any potential disruption to consumers.

        7. Costs and Benefits

        88. In addition to the specific questions noted above, we ask commenters to consider generally the costs and benefits associated with either retaining, sunsetting, or relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition as described herein. We believe that retaining the exclusive contract prohibition in its entirety as it exists today will result in certain costs, such as unnecessarily restricting procompetitive arrangements that in certain instances may foster competition in the video distribution market and promote competition and diversity in the video programming market. While a case-by-case approach, either pursuant to a Section 628(b) complaint (and, potentially, a Section 628(c)(2)(B) complaint) or a market-based petition, will better enable the Commission to consider the unique facts and circumstances presented in each case, this approach will also result in certain costs by requiring the affected parties and the Commission to expend resources litigating and resolving the complaints and petitions. Retaining an exclusive contract prohibition for programming that is demonstrated to be important for competition, non-

        replicable, and without good substitutes (i.e., satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming), may help to reduce these costs by eliminating the need to file complaints with respect to this class of programming. To the extent possible, we encourage commenters to quantify the costs and benefits of the different approaches to the exclusive contract prohibition as described herein. Which of the approaches would be most beneficial to the public? When would the public realize these benefits? Which of these approaches would be least burdensome?

        8. Subdistribution Agreements

        89. We seek comment on the impact of a sunset (complete or partial) of the exclusive contract prohibition on the Commission's rules pertaining to exclusive subdistribution agreements. The Commission's rules define a subdistribution agreement as ``an arrangement by which a local cable operator is given the right by a satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor to distribute the vendor's programming to competing multichannel video programming distributors.'' Based on the exclusive contract prohibition, the Commission in the 1993 Program Access Order adopted certain restrictions on exclusive subdistribution agreements to ``address any incentives for a subdistributor to refuse to sell to a competing MVPD that may be inherent in such rights'' and to ensure ``appropriate safeguards to limit the potential for anticompetitive behavior.'' Specifically, a cable operator engaged in subdistribution (i) may not require a competing MVPD to purchase additional or unrelated programming as a condition of such subdistribution; (ii) may not require a competing MVPD to provide access to private property in exchange for access to programming; (iii) may not charge a competing MVPD more for programming than the satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor itself would be permitted to charge; and (iv) must respond to a request for access to such programming by a competing MVPD within fifteen (15) days of the request and, if the request is denied, the competing MVPD must be permitted to negotiate directly with the satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor. We propose to eliminate these restrictions to the extent the exclusive contract prohibition sunsets and seek comment on this proposal.

        9. Common Carriers and Open Video Systems

        90. The Commission's rules contain provisions pertaining to exclusive contracts involving common carriers and OVS in served areas that mirror the rules applicable to exclusive contracts between cable operators and satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers in served areas. With respect to common carriers, these rules pertain to exclusive contracts between a satellite-delivered, common-carrier-

        affiliated programmer and a common carrier or its affiliate that provides video programming by any means directly to subscribers. With respect to OVS, these rules pertain to exclusive contracts (i) between a satellite-delivered, OVS-affiliated programmer and an OVS or its affiliate that provides video programming on its OVS; and (ii) between a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer and an OVS video programming provider in which a cable operator has an attributable interest. We propose that any amendments we adopt herein to our rules pertaining to exclusive contracts between cable operators and satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers in served areas will apply equally to these rules pertaining to common carriers and OVS. We also propose to conform the rules pertaining to exclusive subdistribution agreements involving OVS to the rules applicable to cable operators and seek comment on this proposal.

        10. Impact of a Sunset on Existing Merger Conditions

        91. We believe that conditions adopted in two previous merger orders may be impacted if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially). We seek comment on this impact below.

      11. Adelphia Order Merger Conditions

        92. Pursuant to merger conditions adopted in the Adelphia Order, certain terrestrially delivered RSNs (``Covered RSNs'') affiliated with TWC are currently required to comply with the program access rules applicable to satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming, including the exclusive contract prohibition.\21\ Among other

        Page 24323

        things, the conditions state as follows with respect to exclusivity (the ``exclusivity conditions''):

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

        \21\ See Applications for Consent to the Assignment and/or Transfer of Control of Licenses, Adelphia Communications Corporation, Assignors to Time Warner Cable, Inc., Assignees, et al., Memorandum Opinion and Order, 21 FCC Rcd 8203, 8274, paras. 156-157 (2006) (``Adelphia Order'') (requiring terrestrially delivered RSNs in which Time Warner has or acquires an attributable interest to comply with the program access rules applicable to satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming, citing 47 CFR 76.1002), 8276, para. 162, and 8336, Appendix B, sec. B.1 (citing 47 CFR 76.1002); see also Time Warner Order, 24 FCC Rcd at 893, para. 26 (approving transaction separating Time Warner from TWC and explaining that the Adelphia Order program access conditions will continue to apply to TWC post-restructuring but will no longer apply to Time Warner). An RSN as defined in the Adelphia Order is ``any non-broadcast video programming service that (1) provides live or same-day distribution within a limited geographic region of sporting events of a sports team that is a member of Major League Baseball, the National Basketball Association, the National Football League, the National Hockey League, NASCAR, NCAA Division I Football, NCAA Division I Basketball and (2) in any year, carries a minimum of either 100 hours of programming that meets the criteria of subheading 1, or 10% of the regular season games of at least one sports team that meets the criteria of subheading 1.'' Adelphia Order, 21 FCC Rcd at 8336, Appendix B, sec. A. While these conditions originally applied to Comcast as well, they were superseded by the Comcast/NBCU Order. See Comcast/NBCU Order, 26 FCC Rcd at 4364, Appendix A, Condition VI.

        (i) ``Time Warner Cable, and its existing or future Covered RSNs, regardless of the means of delivery, shall not offer any such RSN on an exclusive basis to any MVPD, and * * * Time Warner Cable, and its Covered RSNs, regardless of the means of delivery, are required to make such RSNs available to all MVPDs on a non-exclusive basis * * *'';

        (ii) ``Time Warner Cable will not enter into an exclusive distribution arrangement with any such Covered RSN, regardless of the means of delivery''; and

        (iii) ``This exclusive contracts and practices * * * requirement of the program access rules will apply to Time Warner Cable and its Covered RSNs for six years, provided that if the program access rules are modified this condition shall be modified to conform to any revised rules adopted by the Commission.''

        93. These conditions are scheduled to expire in July 2012. Depending on whether and how we revise the exclusive contract prohibition, and if we do so before these conditions expire, we may need to modify these exclusivity conditions to conform to our revised rules. We envision four alternative scenarios. First, to the extent that we retain the exclusive contract prohibition in its entirety as it exists today, including for RSNs, there will be no need to modify the exclusivity conditions because the program access rules will remain the same. Second, to the extent that we retain an exclusive contract prohibition for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming only, there will be no need to modify the exclusivity conditions because the exclusive contract prohibition will remain the same with respect to RSNs. Third, to the extent we establish a process whereby a cable operator or satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer can seek to remove the exclusive contract prohibition on a market-by-market basis, and grant of such a petition includes RSNs, then we would expect to modify the exclusivity conditions to provide that Covered RSNs in markets covered by such a petition (if granted) will no longer be subject to these exclusivity conditions. If the grant of such a petition does not include RSNs, however, there will be no need to modify the exclusivity conditions because the exclusive contract prohibition will remain the same with respect to RSNs. Fourth, to the extent we sunset the exclusive contract prohibition in its entirety, including for RSNs, then we would expect to modify the exclusivity conditions to provide that Covered RSNs will no longer be subject to these exclusivity conditions; rather, exclusive contracts for Covered RSNs may be assessed on a case-by-case basis in response to a program access complaint alleging a violation of Section 628(b) (and, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B)). We seek comment on this interpretation.

      12. Liberty Media Order Merger Conditions

        94. Pursuant to merger conditions adopted in the Liberty Media Order,\22\ certain programmers affiliated with Liberty Media and DIRECTV are subject to the following conditions (the ``exclusivity conditions''), among others:

        \22\ Applications for Consent to the Assignment and/or Transfer of Control of Licenses, News Corporation. and The DIRECTV Group, Inc., Transferors, to Liberty Media Corporation., Transferee, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 23 FCC Rcd 3265 (2008) (``Liberty Media Order''). The conditions state that the term ``Liberty Media'' includes ``any entity or program rights holder in which Liberty Media or John Malone holds an attributable interest. Thus, the term `Liberty Media' includes Discovery Communications.'' Id. at 3340-41 n.3. Moreover, the conditions provide that ``Liberty Media and DIRECTV are prohibited from acquiring an attributable interest in any non-broadcast national or regional programming service while these conditions are in effect if the programming service is not obligated to abide by such conditions.'' Id.

        (i) ``Liberty Media shall not offer any of its existing or future national and regional programming services on an exclusive basis to any MVPD. Liberty Media shall continue to make such services available to all MVPDs on a non-exclusive basis * * *'';

        (ii) ``DIRECTV will not enter into an exclusive distribution arrangement with any Affiliated Program Rights Holder.'';

        (iii) ``As long as Liberty Media holds an attributable interest in DIRECTV, DIRECTV will deal with any Affiliated Program Rights Holder with respect to programming services the Affiliated Program Rights Holder controls as a vertically integrated programmer subject to the program access rules.'';

        (iv) ``These conditions will apply to Liberty Media, DIRECTV, and any Affiliated Program Rights Holder until the later of a determination by the Commission that Liberty Media no longer holds an attributable interest in DIRECTV or the Commission's program access rules no longer remain in effect (provided that if the program access rules are modified these commitments shall be modified, as the Commission deems appropriate, to conform to any revised rules adopted by the Commission).''

        95. These particular Liberty Media Order conditions differ from similar conditions in the Adelphia Order in that (i) they apply not only to RSNs, but to both national and regional programming services; and (ii) they do not expire after the passage of a certain period of time. Depending on whether and how we revise the exclusive contract prohibition of the program access rules, we may need to modify these exclusivity conditions to conform to our revised rules. First, to the extent that we retain the exclusive contract prohibition in its entirety as it exists today, there will be no need to modify the exclusivity conditions because the program access rules will remain the same. Second, to the extent that we retain an exclusive contract prohibition for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming only, there will be no need to modify the exclusivity conditions with respect to RSNs and other ``must have'' programming because the exclusive contract prohibition will remain the same with respect to such programming. With respect to non-RSN programming and other programming that is not deemed ``must have,'' however, we would expect to modify the exclusivity conditions to provide that exclusive contracts involving such programming will no longer be prohibited. To the extent any covered non-RSN/non-``must have'' programming is cable-affiliated, however, exclusive contracts may be assessed on a case-by-case basis in response to a program access complaint alleging a violation of Section 628(b) (and, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B)). Third, to the extent we establish a process whereby a cable operator or satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer can seek to remove the exclusive contract prohibition on a market-by-market basis, and grant of such a petition includes satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming, then we would expect to modify the exclusivity conditions to provide that exclusive contracts in markets covered by such a petition (if granted) will not be prohibited under these conditions. If the grant of such a petition does not include satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated ``must have'' programming, however, there will be no need to modify the exclusivity conditions with respect to RSNs and other ``must have'' programming because the exclusive contract prohibition will remain the same with respect to such programming. Fourth, to the extent we sunset the exclusive contract prohibition in its entirety, including for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated RSNs and other satellite-

        delivered, cable-affiliated

        Page 24324

        ``must have'' programming, then we would expect to modify the exclusivity conditions to provide that exclusive contracts will not be prohibited. Again, however, to the extent any of the covered programming is cable-affiliated, exclusive contracts will be assessed on a case-by-case basis in response to a program access complaint alleging a violation of Section 628(b) (and, potentially, Section 628(c)(2)(B)). We seek comment on this interpretation.\23\

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

        \23\ In contrast to the Adelphia Order and the Liberty Media Order, there is no provision in the Comcast/NBCU Order requiring the conditions adopted therein to be modified to conform to changes the Commission makes to the program access rules. See Comcast/NBCU Order, 26 FCC Rcd at 4381, Appendix A, Condition XX (stating that the conditions will remain in effect for seven years, provided that the Commission will consider a petition from Comcast/NBCU for modification of a condition if they can demonstrate that there has been a material change in circumstances, or that the condition has proven unduly burdensome, such that the Condition is no longer necessary in the public interest). Accordingly, the conditions adopted in the Comcast/NBCU Order will not be affected by the rule changes adopted in this proceeding.

        ---------------------------------------------------------------------------

    2. Potential Revisions to the Program Access Rules To Better Address Alleged Violations

      96. The Commission initially adopted its program access rules in 1993. Other than the previous extensions of the exclusive contract prohibition and certain procedural changes, including the adoption of a process for the award of damages, establishing aspirational deadlines for the processing of complaints, and implementing party-to-party discovery, these rules have remained largely unchanged since this time. We seek comment on how our rules can be improved, especially in light of marketplace developments and commenters' experience with these rules over the past two decades.

      1. Procedural Rules

      97. As an initial matter, while our program access procedural rules provide a defendant with 20 days after service of a complaint to file an answer, the Commission has provided defendants with 45 days from the date of service to file an answer to a Section 628(b) complaint alleging an ``unfair act'' involving terrestrially delivered, cable-

      affiliated programming to ensure that the defendant has adequate time to develop a response. The Commission explained that additional time was appropriate because, unlike complaints alleging a violation of the prohibitions in Section 628(c), a complaint alleging a violation of Section 628(b) entails additional factual inquiries, including whether the allegedly ``unfair act'' at issue has the purpose or effect set forth in Section 628(b). To the extent the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), we propose to adopt the same 45-day answer period in complaint proceedings alleging that an exclusive contract involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming violates Section 628(b). We seek comment on this proposal. Because all complaints alleging a violation of Section 628(b) will involve the claim that the conduct at issue has the purpose or effect set forth in Section 628(b), we propose to amend our rules to provide for a 45-day answer period for all complaints alleging a violation of Section 628(b). We seek comment on this proposal. Are there any other changes we should make to our program access procedural rules to accommodate the case-by-case consideration of exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming under Section 628(b)?

      2. Volume Discounts

      98. We also seek comment on whether our program access rules adequately address potentially discriminatory volume discounts and, if not, how these rules should be revised to address these concerns. Some MVPDs have expressed concern that cable-affiliated programmers charge larger MVPDs less for programming on a per-subscriber basis than smaller MVPDs due to volume discounts, which are based on the number of subscribers the MVPD serves. As a result, smaller MVPDs claim that they are placed at a significant cost disadvantage relative to larger MVPDs. Some commenters have claimed that this price differential is not cost-

      based because program production and acquisition costs are sunk; delivery costs do not vary; and administrative costs are not different. According to some commenters, without a basis in cost, this wholesale practice amounts to price discrimination.

      99. The anti-discrimination provision in Section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Act provides that it is not impermissibly discriminatory for a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer to ``establish different prices, terms, and conditions which take into account economies of scale, cost savings, or other direct and legitimate economic benefits reasonably attributable to the number of subscribers served by the distributor.'' The Commission's rules provide that:

      Vendors may use volume-related justifications to establish price differentials to the extent that such justifications are made available to similarly situated distributors on a technology-neutral basis. When relying upon standardized volume-related factors that are made available to all multichannel video programming distributors using all technologies, the vendor may be required to demonstrate that such volume discounts are reasonably related to direct and legitimate economic benefits reasonably attributable to the number of subscribers served by the distributor if questions arise about the application of that discount. In such demonstrations, vendors will not be required to provide a strict cost justification for the structure of such standard volume-related factors, but may also identify non-cost economic benefits related to increased viewership.

      Thus, the Commission's rules contemplate that an MVPD may file a program access complaint challenging volume-based pricing in certain circumstances. In the Comcast/NBCU Order, the Commission declined to adopt a condition that would prohibit Comcast-NBCU from offering volume-based discounts for its video programming, finding such a prohibition to be unnecessary because ``the specific matter of volume-

      based discounts is adequately addressed by the Commission's program access rules.''

      100. Despite the concerns expressed by some MVPDs regarding allegedly discriminatory volume discounts and the availability of the existing complaint process, the Commission has not received program access complaints alleging that particular volume discounts violate Section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Act. We seek information about specific instances of perceived volume discount discrimination, along with explanations of why the alleged conduct amounts to a violation of the Commission's rules. We seek comment on the reasons for the lack of program access complaints alleging discriminatory volume discounts, despite the apparent concern among some MVPDs regarding this issue. Do our current program access rules and procedures prevent or discourage the filing of legitimate complaints pertaining to this issue? Is the complaint process too costly and time-consuming with respect to complaints alleging price discrimination? If so, we seek comment on how we might improve our rules and procedures to avoid impeding the filing of legitimate complaints. Are there procedural tools we might use, such as establishing rebuttable presumptions, that will expedite the complaint process while ensuring fairness to all parties? While the Commission has stated that satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers may justify volume discounts based on ``non-cost economic benefits'' related to

      Page 24325

      increased viewership, it has not defined these benefits in the rules. Should we continue to consider ``non-cost economic benefits'' on a case-by-case basis due to the various factors, such as advertising and online and VOD offerings, that can be considered in setting prices? Should our rules specifically list those ``non-cost economic benefits'' related to increased viewership that might justify volume discounts? If so, what non-cost economic benefits should be identified? Should these benefits be limited to increased advertising revenues resulting from increased viewership? Should satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers be required to demonstrate in response to a complaint the increase in advertising revenues resulting from licensing programming to a larger MVPD and how this increase justifies the volume discount provided to the larger MVPD relative to the complainant?

      3. Uniform Price Increases

      101. We also seek comment on whether and how we should revise our rules to address uniform price increases imposed by satellite-

      delivered, cable-affiliated programmers. In previous merger decisions, the Commission has discussed the possibility that a vertically integrated cable operator could disadvantage its competitors in the video distribution market by raising the price of a network to all distributors (including itself) to a level greater than that which would be charged by a non-vertically integrated supplier. The Commission explained that a vertically integrated cable operator might employ such a strategy to raise its rivals' costs. Because rival MVPDs would have to pay more for the programming, they would likely respond either by raising their prices to subscribers, not purchasing the programming, or reducing marketing activities. The vertically integrated cable operator could then enjoy a competitive advantage, because the higher price for the programming that it would pay would be an internal transfer that it could disregard when it sets its own prices. By forcing its competitors either to pay more for the programming and increase their retail rates, or forgo purchasing the programming, the vertically integrated cable operator could raise its prices to some extent without losing subscribers. The Commission has also stated that this strategy of uniform price increases does not necessarily violate the anti-discrimination provision of the program access rules because the price increases would be applied to all distributors equally and thus does not involve discriminatory conduct. In previous merger orders, the Commission has sought to address this issue by adopting a baseball-style arbitration remedy to maintain the pre-integration balance of bargaining power between vertically integrated programming networks and rival MVPDs.

      102. We seek comment on whether and how we should revise our rules to address uniform price increases imposed by satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmers. We also seek comment on actual experiences of discriminatory uniform price increases. Is there any basis to interpret the anti-discrimination provision in Section 628(c)(2)(B) as applying to uniform price increases? We note that, in employment law, a practice that appears facially neutral may nonetheless be discriminatory if it has a disparate impact on a certain class. While a uniform price increase appears facially neutral in that it applies to all MVPDs equally, it has a disparate impact on MVPDs that are not affiliated with the cable-affiliated programmer because the price increase is not merely an internal transfer for unaffiliated MVPDs. To the extent that a uniform price increase is not covered by the anti-discrimination provision in Section 628(c)(2)(B), can it be addressed on a case-by-case basis in a Section 628(b) complaint alleging that a uniform price increase is an ``unfair act'' that has the ``purpose or effect'' of ``significantly hindering or preventing'' an MVPD from providing satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming to subscribers or consumers? To the extent that a uniform price increase is actionable under Section 628(c)(2)(B) or Section 628(b), how can we distinguish an anticompetitive uniform price increase intended to raise rivals' costs from a price increase dictated by the market?

  4. Procedural Matters

    1. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Act Analysis

      103. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended (``RFA''), the Commission has prepared this present Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (``IRFA'') concerning the possible significant economic impact on small entities by the policies and rules proposed in the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (``NPRM''). Written public comments are requested on this IRFA. Comments must be identified as responses to the IRFA and must be filed by the deadlines for comments on the NPRM specified supra. The Commission will send a copy of the NPRM, including this IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration (``SBA''). In addition, the NPRM and IRFA (or summaries thereof) will be published in the Federal Register.

      Need for, and Objectives of, the Proposed Rule Changes

      104. We issue the NPRM to seek comment on (i) whether to retain, sunset, or relax one of the several protections afforded to multichannel video programming distributors (``MVPDs'') by the program access rules--the prohibition on exclusive contracts involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming; and (ii) potential revisions to our program access rules to better address alleged violations, including potentially discriminatory volume discounts and uniform price increases.

      105. In areas served by a cable operator, Section 628(c)(2)(D) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended (the ``Act''), generally prohibits exclusive contracts for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming between any cable operator and any cable-affiliated programming vendor (the ``exclusive contract prohibition''). The exclusive contract prohibition applies to all satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming and presumes that an exclusive contract will cause competitive harm in every case, regardless of the type of programming at issue. The exclusive contract prohibition applies only to programming which is delivered via satellite; it does not apply to programming which is delivered via terrestrial facilities. In January 2010, the Commission adopted rules providing for the processing of complaints alleging that an ``unfair act'' involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated programming violates Section 628(b) of the Act. Thus, while an exclusive contract involving satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programming is generally prohibited, an exclusive contract involving terrestrially delivered, cable-affiliated programming is permitted unless the Commission finds in response to a complaint that it violates Section 628(b) of the Act.

      106. In Section 628(c)(5) of the Act, Congress provided that the exclusive contract prohibition would cease to be effective on October 5, 2002, unless the Commission found that it ``continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.'' In June 2002, the Commission found that the exclusive contract prohibition continued to be necessary to preserve

      Page 24326

      and protect competition and diversity and retained the exclusive contract prohibition for five years, until October 5, 2007. The Commission provided that, during the year before the expiration of the five-year extension, it would conduct a second review to determine whether the exclusive contract prohibition continued to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming. After conducting such a review, the Commission in September 2007 concluded that the exclusive contract prohibition was still necessary, and it retained the prohibition for five more years, until October 5, 2012. The Commission again provided that, during the year before the expiration of the five-year extension, it would conduct a third review to determine whether the exclusive contract prohibition continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.

      107. Accordingly, in this NPRM, we initiate the third review of the necessity of the exclusive contract prohibition. In the NPRM, we present certain data on the current state of competition in the video distribution market and the video programming market, and we invite commenters to submit more recent data or empirical analyses. We seek comment on whether current conditions in the video marketplace support retaining, sunsetting, or relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition. To the extent that the data do not support retaining the exclusive contract prohibition as it exists today, we seek comment on whether we can preserve and protect competition in the video distribution market by either:

      Sunsetting the exclusive contract prohibition in its entirety and instead relying solely on existing protections provided by the program access rules that will not sunset: (i) The case-by-case consideration of exclusive contracts pursuant to Section 628(b) of the Act; (ii) the prohibition on discrimination in Section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Act; and (iii) the prohibition on undue or improper influence in Section 628(c)(2)(A) of the Act; or

      Relaxing the exclusive contract prohibition by (i) establishing a process whereby a cable operator or satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer can seek to remove the prohibition on a market-by-market basis based on the extent of competition in the market; (ii) retaining the prohibition only for satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated Regional Sports Networks (``RSNs'') and any other satellite delivered, cable-affiliated programming that the record here establishes as being important for competition and non-replicable and having no good substitutes; and/or (iii) other ways commenters propose.

      We seek comment also on (i) how to implement a sunset (complete or partial) to minimize any potential disruption to consumers; (ii) the First Amendment implications of the alternatives discussed herein; (iii) the costs and benefits of the alternatives discussed herein; and (iv) the impact of a sunset on existing merger conditions.

      108. In addition, we seek comment in the NPRM on potential improvements to the program access rules to better address potential violations. With the exception of certain procedural revisions and the previous extensions of the exclusive contract prohibition, the program access rules have remained largely unchanged in the almost two decades since the Commission originally adopted them in 1993. We seek comment on, among other things, whether our rules adequately address potentially discriminatory volume discounts and uniform price increases and, if not, how these rules should be revised to address these concerns.

      Legal Basis

      109. The proposed action is authorized pursuant to Sections 4(i), 4(j), 303(r), and 628 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 154(i), 154(j), 303(r), and 548.

      Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to Which the Proposed Rules Will Apply

      110. The RFA directs agencies to provide a description of, and where feasible, an estimate of the number of small entities that may be affected by the proposed rules, if adopted. The RFA generally defines the term ``small entity'' as having the same meaning as the terms ``small business,'' ``small organization,'' and ``small governmental jurisdiction.'' In addition, the term ``small business'' has the same meaning as the term ``small business concern'' under the Small Business Act. A small business concern is one which: (1) Is independently owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and (3) satisfies any additional criteria established by the SBA. Below, we provide a description of such small entities, as well as an estimate of the number of such small entities, where feasible.

      111. Wired Telecommunications Carriers. The 2007 North American Industry Classification System (``NAICS'') defines ``Wired Telecommunications Carriers'' as follows: ``This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in operating and/or providing access to transmission facilities and infrastructure that they own and/or lease for the transmission of voice, data, text, sound, and video using wired telecommunications networks. Transmission facilities may be based on a single technology or a combination of technologies. Establishments in this industry use the wired telecommunications network facilities that they operate to provide a variety of services, such as wired telephony services, including VoIP services; wired (cable) audio and video programming distribution; and wired broadband Internet services. By exception, establishments providing satellite television distribution services using facilities and infrastructure that they operate are included in this industry.'' The SBA has developed a small business size standard for wireline firms within the broad economic census category, ``Wired Telecommunications Carriers.'' Under this category, the SBA deems a wireline business to be small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 3,188 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of this total, 3,144 had employment of 999 or fewer, and 44 firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. Thus under this category and the associated small business size standard, the majority of these firms can be considered small.

      112. Cable Television Distribution Services. Since 2007, these services have been defined within the broad economic census category of Wired Telecommunications Carriers; that category is defined above. The SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: All such firms having 1,500 or fewer employees. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 3,188 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of this total, 3,144 had employment of 999 or fewer, and 44 firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. Thus under this category and the associated small business size standard, the majority of these firms can be considered small.

      113. Cable Companies and Systems. The Commission has also developed its own small business size standards, for the purpose of cable rate regulation. Under the Commission's rules, a ``small cable company'' is one serving 400,000 or fewer subscribers nationwide. Industry data indicate that all but ten

      Page 24327

      cable operators nationwide are small under this size standard. In addition, under the Commission's rules, a ``small system'' is a cable system serving 15,000 or fewer subscribers. Industry data indicate that, of 6,101 systems nationwide, 4,410 systems have under 10,000 subscribers, and an additional 258 systems have 10,000-19,999 subscribers. Thus, under this standard, most cable systems are small.

      114. Cable System Operators. The Communications Act of 1934, as amended, also contains a size standard for small cable system operators, which is ``a cable operator that, directly or through an affiliate, serves in the aggregate fewer than 1 percent of all subscribers in the United States and is not affiliated with any entity or entities whose gross annual revenues in the aggregate exceed $250,000,000.'' The Commission has determined that an operator serving fewer than 677,000 subscribers shall be deemed a small operator if its annual revenues, when combined with the total annual revenues of all its affiliates, do not exceed $250 million in the aggregate. Industry data indicate that all but nine cable operators nationwide are small under this subscriber size standard. We note that the Commission neither requests nor collects information on whether cable system operators are affiliated with entities whose gross annual revenues exceed $250 million, and therefore we are unable to estimate more accurately the number of cable system operators that would qualify as small under this size standard.

      115. Direct Broadcast Satellite (``DBS'') Service. DBS service is a nationally distributed subscription service that delivers video and audio programming via satellite to a small parabolic ``dish'' antenna at the subscriber's location. DBS, by exception, is now included in the SBA's broad economic census category, ``Wired Telecommunications Carriers,'' which was developed for small wireline firms. Under this category, the SBA deems a wireline business to be small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 3,188 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of this total, 3,144 had employment of 999 or fewer, and 44 firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. Thus under this category and the associated small business size standard, the majority of these firms can be considered small. Currently, only two entities provide DBS service, which requires a great investment of capital for operation: DIRECTV and EchoStar Communications Corporation (``EchoStar'') (marketed as the DISH Network). Each currently offers subscription services. DIRECTV and EchoStar each report annual revenues that are in excess of the threshold for a small business. Because DBS service requires significant capital, we believe it is unlikely that a small entity as defined by the SBA would have the financial wherewithal to become a DBS service provider.

      116. Satellite Master Antenna Television (SMATV) Systems, also known as Private Cable Operators (PCOs). SMATV systems or PCOs are video distribution facilities that use closed transmission paths without using any public right-of-way. They acquire video programming and distribute it via terrestrial wiring in urban and suburban multiple dwelling units such as apartments and condominiums, and commercial multiple tenant units such as hotels and office buildings. SMATV systems or PCOs are now included in the SBA's broad economic census category, ``Wired Telecommunications Carriers,'' which was developed for small wireline firms. Under this category, the SBA deems a wireline business to be small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 3,188 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of this total, 3,144 had employment of 999 or fewer, and 44 firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. Thus, under this category and the associated small business size standard, the majority of these firms can be considered small.

      117. Home Satellite Dish (``HSD'') Service. HSD or the large dish segment of the satellite industry is the original satellite-to-home service offered to consumers, and involves the home reception of signals transmitted by satellites operating generally in the C-band frequency. Unlike DBS, which uses small dishes, HSD antennas are between four and eight feet in diameter and can receive a wide range of unscrambled (free) programming and scrambled programming purchased from program packagers that are licensed to facilitate subscribers' receipt of video programming. Because HSD provides subscription services, HSD falls within the SBA-recognized definition of Wired Telecommunications Carriers. The SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: All such firms having 1,500 or fewer employees. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 3,188 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of this total, 3,144 had employment of 999 or fewer, and 44 firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. Thus, under this category and the associated small business size standard, the majority of these firms can be considered small.

      118. Broadband Radio Service and Educational Broadband Service. Broadband Radio Service systems, previously referred to as Multipoint Distribution Service (MDS) and Multichannel Multipoint Distribution Service (MMDS) systems, and ``wireless cable,'' transmit video programming to subscribers and provide two-way high speed data operations using the microwave frequencies of the Broadband Radio Service (BRS) and Educational Broadband Service (EBS) (previously referred to as the Instructional Television Fixed Service (ITFS)). In connection with the 1996 BRS auction, the Commission established a small business size standard as an entity that had annual average gross revenues of no more than $40 million in the previous three calendar years. The BRS auctions resulted in 67 successful bidders obtaining licensing opportunities for 493 Basic Trading Areas (BTAs). Of the 67 auction winners, 61 met the definition of a small business. BRS also includes licensees of stations authorized prior to the auction. At this time, we estimate that of the 61 small business BRS auction winners, 48 remain small business licensees. In addition to the 48 small businesses that hold BTA authorizations, there are approximately 392 incumbent BRS licensees that are considered small entities. After adding the number of small business auction licensees to the number of incumbent licensees not already counted, we find that there are currently approximately 440 BRS licensees that are defined as small businesses under either the SBA or the Commission's rules. In 2009, the Commission conducted Auction 86, the sale of 78 licenses in the BRS areas. The Commission offered three levels of bidding credits: (i) A bidder with attributed average annual gross revenues that exceed $15 million and do not exceed $40 million for the preceding three years (small business) received a 15 percent discount on its winning bid; (ii) a bidder with attributed average annual gross revenues that exceed $3 million and do not exceed $15 million for the preceding three years (very small business) received a 25 percent discount on its winning bid; and (iii) a bidder with attributed average annual gross revenues that do not exceed $3 million

      Page 24328

      for the preceding three years (entrepreneur) received a 35 percent discount on its winning bid. Auction 86 concluded in 2009 with the sale of 61 licenses. Of the ten winning bidders, two bidders that claimed small business status won 4 licenses; one bidder that claimed very small business status won three licenses; and two bidders that claimed entrepreneur status won six licenses.

      119. In addition, the SBA's Cable Television Distribution Services small business size standard is applicable to EBS. There are presently 2,032 EBS licensees. All but 100 of these licenses are held by educational institutions. Educational institutions are included in this analysis as small entities. Thus, we estimate that at least 1,932 licensees are small businesses. Since 2007, Cable Television Distribution Services have been defined within the broad economic census category of Wired Telecommunications Carriers; that category is defined as follows: ``This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in operating and/or providing access to transmission facilities and infrastructure that they own and/or lease for the transmission of voice, data, text, sound, and video using wired telecommunications networks. Transmission facilities may be based on a single technology or a combination of technologies.'' The SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: All such firms having 1,500 or fewer employees. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 3,188 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of this total, 3,144 had employment of 999 or fewer, and 44 firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. Thus, under this category and the associated small business size standard, the majority of these firms can be considered small.

      120. Fixed Microwave Services. Microwave services include common carrier, private-operational fixed, and broadcast auxiliary radio services. They also include the Local Multipoint Distribution Service (LMDS), the Digital Electronic Message Service (DEMS), and the 24 GHz Service, where licensees can choose between common carrier and non-

      common carrier status. At present, there are approximately 31,428 common carrier fixed licensees and 79,732 private operational-fixed licensees and broadcast auxiliary radio licensees in the microwave services. There are approximately 120 LMDS licensees, three DEMS licensees, and three 24 GHz licensees. The Commission has not yet defined a small business with respect to microwave services. For purposes of the IRFA, we will use the SBA's definition applicable to Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except satellite)--i.e., an entity with no more than 1,500 persons. Under the present and prior categories, the SBA has deemed a wireless business to be small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. For the category of Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite), Census data for 2007, which supersede data contained in the 2002 Census, show that there were 1,383 firms that operated that year. Of those 1,383, 1,368 had fewer than 1000 employees, and 15 firms had 1000 employees or more. Thus under this category and the associated small business size standard, the majority of firms can be considered small. We note that the number of firms does not necessarily track the number of licensees. We estimate that virtually all of the Fixed Microwave licensees (excluding broadcast auxiliary licensees) would qualify as small entities under the SBA definition.

      121. Open Video Systems. The open video system (``OVS'') framework was established in 1996, and is one of four statutorily recognized options for the provision of video programming services by local exchange carriers. The OVS framework provides opportunities for the distribution of video programming other than through cable systems. Because OVS operators provide subscription services, OVS falls within the SBA small business size standard covering cable services, which is ``Wired Telecommunications Carriers.'' The SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: All such firms having 1,500 or fewer employees. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 3,188 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of this total, 3,144 had employment of 999 or fewer, and 44 firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. Thus, under this category and the associated small business size standard, the majority of these firms can be considered small. In addition, we note that the Commission has certified some OVS operators, with some now providing service. Broadband service providers (``BSPs'') are currently the only significant holders of OVS certifications or local OVS franchises. The Commission does not have financial or employment information regarding the entities authorized to provide OVS, some of which may not yet be operational. Thus, at least some of the OVS operators may qualify as small entities.

      122. Cable and Other Subscription Programming. The Census Bureau defines this category as follows: ``This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in operating studios and facilities for the broadcasting of programs on a subscription or fee basis. * * * These establishments produce programming in their own facilities or acquire programming from external sources. The programming material is usually delivered to a third party, such as cable systems or direct-to-

      home satellite systems, for transmission to viewers.'' The SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: All such firms having $15 million dollars or less in annual revenues. To gauge small business prevalence in the Cable and Other Subscription Programming industries, the Commission relies on data currently available from the U.S. Census for the year 2007. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 396 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of that number, 325 operated with annual revenues of $9,999,999 million dollars or less. Seventy-one (71) operated with annual revenues of between $10 million and $100 million or more. Thus, under this category and associated small business size standard, the majority of firms can be considered small.

      123. Small Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers. We have included small incumbent local exchange carriers in this present RFA analysis. A ``small business'' under the RFA is one that, inter alia, meets the pertinent small business size standard (e.g., a telephone communications business having 1,500 or fewer employees), and ``is not dominant in its field of operation.'' The SBA's Office of Advocacy contends that, for RFA purposes, small incumbent local exchange carriers are not dominant in their field of operation because any such dominance is not ``national'' in scope. We have therefore included small incumbent local exchange carriers in this RFA analysis, although we emphasize that this RFA action has no effect on Commission analyses and determinations in other, non-RFA contexts.

      124. Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers (``LECs''). Neither the Commission nor the SBA has developed a small business size standard specifically for incumbent local exchange services. The appropriate size standard under SBA rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that size standard, such

      Page 24329

      a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 3,188 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of this total, 3,144 had employment of 999 or fewer, and 44 firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. Thus, under this category and the associated small business size standard, the majority of these firms can be considered small.

      125. Competitive Local Exchange Carriers, Competitive Access Providers (CAPs), ``Shared-Tenant Service Providers,'' and ``Other Local Service Providers.'' Neither the Commission nor the SBA has developed a small business size standard specifically for these service providers. The appropriate size standard under SBA rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 3,188 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of this total, 3,144 had employment of 999 or fewer, and 44 firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. Thus, under this category and the associated small business size standard, the majority of these firms can be considered small. Consequently, the Commission estimates that most providers of competitive local exchange service, competitive access providers, ``Shared-Tenant Service Providers,'' and ``Other Local Service Providers'' are small entities.

      126. Motion Picture and Video Production. The Census Bureau defines this category as follows: ``This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in producing, or producing and distributing motion pictures, videos, television programs, or television commercials.'' We note that firms in this category may be engaged in various industries, including cable programming. Specific figures are not available regarding how many of these firms produce and/or distribute programming for cable television. The SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: All such firms having $29.5 million dollars or less in annual revenues. To gauge small business prevalence in the Motion Picture and Video Production industries, the Commission relies on data currently available from the U.S. Census for the year 2007. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 9,095 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of these, 8995 had annual receipts of $24,999,999 or less, and 100 had annual receipts ranging from not less that $25,000,000 to $100,000,000 or more. Thus, under this category and associated small business size standard, the majority of firms can be considered small.

      127. Motion Picture and Video Distribution. The Census Bureau defines this category as follows: ``This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in acquiring distribution rights and distributing film and video productions to motion picture theaters, television networks and stations, and exhibitors.'' We note that firms in this category may be engaged in various industries, including cable programming. Specific figures are not available regarding how many of these firms produce and/or distribute programming for cable television. The SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: All such firms having $29.5 million dollars or less in annual revenues. To gauge small business prevalence in the Motion Picture and Video Distribution industries, the Commission relies on data currently available from the U.S. Census for the year 2007. Census Bureau data for 2007, which now supersede data from the 2002 Census, show that there were 450 firms in this category that operated for the entire year. Of these, 434 had annual receipts of $24,999,999 or less, and 16 had annual receipts ranging from not less that $25,000,000 to $100,000,000 or more. Thus, under this category and associated small business size standard, the majority of firms can be considered small.

      Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping, and Other Compliance Requirements

      128. Certain proposed rule changes discussed in the NPRM would affect reporting, recordkeeping, or other compliance requirements. First, even if the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), the Commission recognizes that other existing protections will remain in effect. Namely, an MVPD would still have the option to file a complaint with the Commission alleging that an exclusive contract between a cable operator and a satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer involving satellite-delivered, cable-

      affiliated programming is an unfair act in violation of Section 628(b) of the Act and Section 76.1001(a) of the Commission's rules. An MVPD may also have the option of filing a discrimination complaint under Section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Act, which would provide some protection for competitive MVPDs should the exclusive contract prohibition sunset (wholly or partially). Further, the NPRM seeks comment on the extent to which undue influence complaints under Section 628(c)(2)(A) may also provide some protection for competitive MVPDs should the exclusive contract prohibition sunset (wholly or partially). Second, rather than sunsetting the exclusive contract prohibition in its entirety, the Commission seeks comment on whether it should instead relax the exclusivity prohibition, such as by establishing a process whereby a cable operator or satellite-delivered, cable-affiliated programmer can seek to remove the exclusive contract prohibition on a market-by-market basis based on the extent of competition in the market. The Commission seeks comment on the details of any such process for removing the exclusive contract prohibition on a market-by-market basis. Third, the Commission proposes to adopt a 45-day answer period in complaint proceedings alleging a violation of Section 628(b). Fourth, the NPRM seeks comment on how the Commission might improve its rules and procedures to avoid impeding the filing of legitimate complaints alleging that particular volume discounts violate Section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Act. Specifically, the Commission asks whether satellite-

      delivered, cable-affiliated programmers should be required to demonstrate in response to a complaint the increase in advertising revenues resulting from licensing programming to a larger MVPD and how this increase justifies the volume discount provided to the larger MVPD relative to the complaint.

      Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Impact on Small Entities and Significant Alternatives Considered

      129. The RFA requires an agency to describe any significant alternatives that it has considered in reaching its proposed approach, which may include the following four alternatives (among others): (1) The establishment of differing compliance or reporting requirements or timetables that take into account the resources available to small entities; (2) the clarification, consolidation, or simplification of compliance or reporting requirements under the rule for small entities; (3) the use of performance, rather than design, standards; and (4) an exemption from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for small entities.

      130. First, regarding the potential sunset or relaxation of the exclusive contract prohibition, the NPRM seeks

      Page 24330

      comment on what impact the retention of the exclusive contract prohibition has had on the general state of competition among MVPDs in the video distribution market. More specifically, the NPRM asks how a sunset or relaxation of the exclusive contract prohibition would affect competition in the video distribution market, and how a sunset or relaxation would affect the potential entry of new competitors in the market. The NPRM also seeks comment on how the current state of cable system clustering and cable market share in regional markets should affect the Commission's decision on whether to retain, sunset, or relax the exclusive contract prohibition. Further, it asks whether the current state of horizontal consolidation in the cable industry has increased or decreased incentives for anticompetitive foreclosure of access to vertically integrated programming. The NPRM asks whether competitive MVPDs have the resources to invest in creating their own video programming. Overall, the Commission's analysis is focused on whether the exclusive contract prohibition ``continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.''

      131. Second, to the extent the exclusive contract prohibition were to sunset (wholly or partially), the NPRM seeks comment on ways to reduce burdens on both complainants and defendants in connection with complaints alleging that an exclusive contract involving satellite-

      delivered, cable-affiliated programming violates Section 628(b) (or Section 628(c)(2)(B)) of the Act.

      132. Third, regarding the potential changes to our procedural rules governing program access complaints, we find that the changes would benefit regulated entities, including those that are small entities. Specifically, small entities may benefit from the proposed lengthier 45-day period within which to file an answer. They may also benefit from rules addressing potentially discriminatory volume discounts and uniform price increases.

      Federal Rules That May Duplicate, Overlap, or Conflict With the Proposed Rule

      133. None.

    2. Paperwork Reduction Act

      134. This document contains proposed new information collection requirements. The Commission, as part of its continuing effort to reduce paperwork burdens, invites the general public and the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) to comment on the information collection requirements contained in this document, as required by the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995. In addition, pursuant to the Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, we seek specific comment on how we might ``further reduce the information collection burden for small business concerns with fewer than 25 employees.''

    3. Ex Parte Rules

      135. Permit-But-Disclose. The proceeding this Notice initiates shall be treated as a ``permit-but-disclose'' proceeding in accordance with the Commission's ex parte rules. Persons making ex parte presentations must file a copy of any written presentation or a memorandum summarizing any oral presentation within two business days after the presentation (unless a different deadline applicable to the Sunshine period applies). Persons making oral ex parte presentations are reminded that memoranda summarizing the presentation must (1) list all persons attending or otherwise participating in the meeting at which the ex parte presentation was made, and (2) summarize all data presented and arguments made during the presentation. If the presentation consisted in whole or in part of the presentation of data or arguments already reflected in the presenter's written comments, memoranda or other filings in the proceeding, the presenter may provide citations to such data or arguments in his or her prior comments, memoranda, or other filings (specifying the relevant page and/or paragraph numbers where such data or arguments can be found) in lieu of summarizing them in the memorandum. Documents shown or given to Commission staff during ex parte meetings are deemed to be written ex parte presentations and must be filed consistent with rule 1.1206(b). In proceedings governed by rule 1.49(f) or for which the Commission has made available a method of electronic filing, written ex parte presentations and memoranda summarizing oral ex parte presentations, and all attachments thereto, must be filed through the electronic comment filing system available for that proceeding, and must be filed in their native format (e.g., .doc, .xml, .ppt, searchable .pdf). Participants in this proceeding should familiarize themselves with the Commission's ex parte rules.

    4. Filing Requirements

      136. Comments and Replies. Pursuant to Sections 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission's rules, interested parties may file comments and reply comments on or before the dates indicated on the first page of this document. Comments may be filed using the Commission's Electronic Comment Filing System (``ECFS'').

      Electronic Filers: Comments may be filed electronically using the Internet by accessing the ECFS: http://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs2/.

      Paper Filers: Parties who choose to file by paper must file an original and one copy of each filing. If more than one docket or rulemaking number appears in the caption of this proceeding, filers must submit two additional copies for each additional docket or rulemaking number.

      Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by commercial overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal Service mail. All filings must be addressed to the Commission's Secretary, Office of the Secretary, Federal Communications Commission.

      cir All hand-delivered or messenger-delivered paper filings for the Commission's Secretary must be delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445 12th St. SW., Room TW-A325, Washington, DC 20554. The filing hours are 8 a.m. to 7 p.m. All hand deliveries must be held together with rubber bands or fasteners. Any envelopes and boxes must be disposed of before entering the building.

      cir Commercial overnight mail (other than U.S. Postal Service Express Mail and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9300 East Hampton Drive, Capitol Heights, MD 20743.

      cir U.S. Postal Service first-class, Express, and Priority mail must be addressed to 445 12th Street SW., Washington, DC 20554.

      137. Availability of Documents. Comments, reply comments, and ex parte submissions will be available for public inspection during regular business hours in the FCC Reference Center, Federal Communications Commission, 445 12th Street SW., CY-A257, Washington, DC 20554. These documents will also be available via ECFS. Documents will be available electronically in ASCII, Microsoft Word, and/or Adobe Acrobat.

      138. People with Disabilities. To request materials in accessible formats for people with disabilities (braille, large print, electronic files, audio format), send an email to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the FCC's Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau at (202) 418-0530 (voice), (202) 418-0432 (TTY).

      139. Additional Information. For additional information on this

      Page 24331

      proceeding, contact David Konczal, David.Konczal@fcc.gov, or Diana Sokolow, Diana.Sokolow@fcc.gov, of the Media Bureau, Policy Division, (202) 418-2120.

  5. Ordering Clauses

    140. Accordingly, It is ordered that pursuant to the authority found in Sections 4(i), 4(j), 303(r), and 628 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. 154(i), 154(j), 303(r), and 548, this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking is adopted.

    141. It is further ordered that the Commission's Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, shall send a copy of this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, including the Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration.

    List of Subjects in 47 CFR Part 76

    Cable television, Reporting and recordkeeping requirements.

    Federal Communications Commission.

    Sheryl D. Todd,

    Deputy Secretary.

    Proposed Rules

    For the reasons discussed in the preamble, the Federal Communications Commission proposes to amend 47 CFR part 76 as follows:

    PART 76--MULTICHANNEL VIDEO AND CABLE TELEVISION SERVICE

    1. The authority citation for Part 76 continues to read as follows:

    Authority: 47 U.S.C. 151, 152, 153, 154, 301, 302, 302a, 303, 303a, 307, 308, 309, 312, 315, 317, 325, 339, 340, 341, 503, 521, 522, 531, 532, 534, 535, 536, 537, 543, 544, 544a, 545, 548, 549, 552, 554, 556, 558, 560, 561, 571, 572 and 573.

    2. Section 76.1000 is amended by adding paragraph (n) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1000 Definitions.

    * * * * *

    (n) Regional Sports Network. The term ``Regional Sports Network'' means video programming that:

    (1) Provides live or same-day distribution within a limited geographic region of sporting events of a sports team that is a member of Major League Baseball, the National Basketball Association, the National Football League, the National Hockey League, NASCAR, NCAA Division I Football, NCAA Division I Basketball, Liga de Beacuteisbol Profesional de Puerto Rico, Baloncesto Superior Nacional de Puerto Rico, Liga Mayor de Fuacutetbol Nacional de Puerto Rico, and the Puerto Rico Islanders of the United Soccer League's First Division; and

    (2) In any year, carries a minimum of either 100 hours of programming that meets the criteria of paragraph (n)(1) of this section, or 10 percent of the regular season games of at least one sports team that meets the criteria of paragraph (n)(1) of this section.

    Alternative 1:

    3. Section 76.1002 is amended by revising paragraph (c)(3) and (6) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1002 Specific unfair practices prohibited.

    * * * * *

    (c) * * *

    (3) Specific arrangements: Subdistribution agreements--(i) Unserved and served areas. No cable operator shall enter into any subdistribution agreement or arrangement for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, with respect to areas served or unserved by a cable operator, unless such agreement or arrangement complies with the limitations set forth in paragraph (c)(3)(ii) of this section.

    (ii) Limitations on subdistribution agreements. No cable operator engaged in subdistribution of satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming may require a competing multichannel video programming distributor to

    (A) Purchase additional or unrelated programming as a condition of such subdistribution; or

    (B) Provide access to private property in exchange for access to programming. In addition, a subdistributor may not charge a competing multichannel video programming distributor more for said programming than the satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor itself would be permitted to charge. Any cable operator acting as a subdistributor of satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming must respond to a request for access to such programming by a competing multichannel video programming distributor within fifteen (15) days of the request. If the request is denied, the competing multichannel video programming distributor must be permitted to negotiate directly with the satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor.

    * * * * *

    (6) Sunset provision. The prohibition of exclusive contracts set forth in paragraph (c)(2) of this section shall cease to be effective on October 5, 2017, unless the Commission finds, during a proceeding to be conducted during the year preceding such date, that said prohibition continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.

    * * * * *

    Alternative 2:

    4. Section 76.1002 is amended by removing and reserving paragraph (c)(2), revising paragraph (c)(3) through (5), and removing paragraph (c)(6) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1002 Specific unfair practices prohibited.

    * * * * *

    (c) * * *

    (3) Specific arrangements: Subdistribution agreements--(i) Unserved areas. No cable operator shall enter into any subdistribution agreement or arrangement for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest for distribution to persons in areas not served by a cable operator as of October 5, 1992 unless such agreement or arrangement complies with the limitations set forth in paragraph (c)(3)(ii) of this section.

    (ii) Limitations on subdistribution agreements in unserved areas. No cable operator engaged in subdistribution of satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming may require a competing multichannel video programming distributor to

    (A) Purchase additional or unrelated programming as a condition of such subdistribution; or

    (B) Provide access to private property in exchange for access to programming. In addition, a subdistributor may not charge a competing multichannel video programming distributor more for said programming than the satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor itself would be permitted to charge. Any cable operator acting as a subdistributor of satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming must respond to a request for access to such programming by a competing multichannel video programming distributor within fifteen (15) days of the request. If the request is denied, the competing multichannel video programming distributor must be

    Page 24332

    permitted to negotiate directly with the satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor.

    (4) Public interest determination. In determining whether an exclusive contract is in the public interest for purposes of paragraph (c)(5) of this section, the Commission will consider each of the following factors with respect to the effect of such contract on the distribution of video programming in areas that are served by a cable operator:

    (i) The effect of such exclusive contract on the development of competition in local and national multichannel video programming distribution markets;

    (ii) The effect of such exclusive contract on competition from multichannel video programming distribution technologies other than cable;

    (iii) The effect of such exclusive contract on the attraction of capital investment in the production and distribution of new satellite cable programming;

    (iv) The effect of such exclusive contract on diversity of programming in the multichannel video programming distribution market; and

    (v) The duration of the exclusive contract.

    (5) Commission approval required. Any cable operator, satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, or satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest must submit a ``Petition for Exclusivity'' to the Commission and receive approval from the Commission to preclude the filing of complaints alleging that an exclusive contract, or practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, with respect to areas served by a cable operator violates section 628(b) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and Sec. 76.1001(a), or section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and paragraph (b) of this section.

    (i) The petition for exclusivity shall contain those portions of the contract relevant to exclusivity, including:

    (A) A description of the programming service;

    (B) The extent and duration of exclusivity proposed; and

    (C) Any other terms or provisions directly related to exclusivity or to any of the criteria set forth in paragraph (c)(4) of this section. The petition for exclusivity shall also include a statement setting forth the petitioner's reasons to support a finding that the contract is in the public interest, addressing each of the five factors set forth in paragraph (c)(4) of this section.

    (ii) Any competing multichannel video programming distributor affected by the proposed exclusivity may file an opposition to the petition for exclusivity within thirty (30) days of the date on which the petition is placed on public notice, setting forth its reasons to support a finding that the contract is not in the public interest under the criteria set forth in paragraph (c)(4) of this section. Any such formal opposition must be served on petitioner on the same day on which it is filed with the Commission.

    (iii) The petitioner may file a response within ten (10) days of receipt of any formal opposition. The Commission will then approve or deny the petition for exclusivity.

    * * * * *

    Alternative 3:

    5. Section 76.1002 is amended by revising paragraph (c)(2) through (3) and (5), removing and reserving paragraph (c)(6), and adding paragraph (c)(7) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1002 Specific unfair practices prohibited.

    * * * * *

    (c) * * *

    (2) Served areas. No cable operator shall enter into any exclusive contracts, or engage in any practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, with respect to areas served by a cable operator, unless:

    (i) The Commission determines in accordance with paragraph (c)(4) of this section that such contract, practice, activity or arrangement is in the public interest; or

    (ii) Such contract, practice, activity or arrangement pertains to a geographic area for which a petition for sunset has been granted pursuant to paragraph (c)(7) of this section.

    (3) Specific arrangements: Subdistribution agreements--(i) Unserved and served areas. No cable operator shall enter into any subdistribution agreement or arrangement for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, with respect to areas served or unserved by a cable operator, unless such agreement or arrangement complies with the limitations set forth in paragraph (c)(3)(ii) of this section.

    (ii) Limitations on subdistribution agreements. No cable operator engaged in subdistribution of satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming may require a competing multichannel video programming distributor to

    (A) Purchase additional or unrelated programming as a condition of such subdistribution; or

    (B) Provide access to private property in exchange for access to programming. In addition, a subdistributor may not charge a competing multichannel video programming distributor more for said programming than the satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor itself would be permitted to charge. Any cable operator acting as a subdistributor of satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming must respond to a request for access to such programming by a competing multichannel video programming distributor within fifteen (15) days of the request. If the request is denied, the competing multichannel video programming distributor must be permitted to negotiate directly with the satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor.

    (iii) Exceptions. Paragraph (c)(3) of this section shall not apply in a geographic area where a petition for sunset has been granted pursuant to paragraph (c)(7) of this section.

    * * * * *

    (5) Commission approval required. (i) Any cable operator, satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, or satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest must submit a ``Petition for Exclusivity'' to the Commission and receive approval from the Commission:

    (A) Prior to enforcing or entering into an exclusive contract, or practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, subject to paragraph (c)(2) of this section that pertains to a geographic area for which a petition for sunset has not been granted pursuant to paragraph (c)(7) of this section; and

    (B) To preclude the filing of complaints alleging that an exclusive contract, or practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, with respect to areas served by a cable operator violates section 628(b)

    Page 24333

    of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and Sec. 76.1001(a) of this part, or section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and paragraph (b) of this section.

    (ii) The petition for exclusivity shall contain those portions of the contract relevant to exclusivity, including:

    (A) A description of the programming service;

    (B) The extent and duration of exclusivity proposed; and

    (C) Any other terms or provisions directly related to exclusivity or to any of the criteria set forth in paragraph (c)(4) of this section. The petition for exclusivity shall also include a statement setting forth the petitioner's reasons to support a finding that the contract is in the public interest, addressing each of the five factors set forth in paragraph (c)(4) of this section.

    (iii) Any competing multichannel video programming distributor affected by the proposed exclusivity may file an opposition to the petition for exclusivity within thirty (30) days of the date on which the petition is placed on public notice, setting forth its reasons to support a finding that the contract is not in the public interest under the criteria set forth in paragraph (c)(4) of this section. Any such formal opposition must be served on petitioner on the same day on which it is filed with the Commission.

    (iv) The petitioner may file a response within ten (10) days of receipt of any formal opposition. The Commission will then approve or deny the petition for exclusivity.

    * * * * *

    (7) Petition for Sunset. Any cable operator, satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, or satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest seeking to remove the prohibition on exclusive contracts and practices, activities or arrangements tantamount to an exclusive contract set forth in paragraph (c)(2) of this section may submit a ``Petition for Sunset'' to the Commission.

    (i) The petition for sunset shall specify the geographic area for which a sunset of the prohibition set forth in paragraph (c)(2) of this section is sought and shall include a statement setting forth the petitioner's reasons to support a finding that such prohibition is not necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming in the geographic area specified.

    (ii) Any competing multichannel video programming distributor or other interested party affected by the petition for sunset may file an opposition to the petition within forty-five (45) days of the date on which the petition is placed on public notice, setting forth its reasons to support a finding that such prohibition continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming. Any such formal opposition must be served on the petitioner on the same day on which it is filed with the Commission.

    (iii) The petitioner may file a response within fifteen (15) days of receipt of any formal opposition.

    (iv) If the Commission finds that the prohibition is not necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming, then the prohibition set forth in paragraph (c)(2) of this section shall no longer apply in the geographic area specified in the decision of the Commission.

    * * * * *

    Alternative 4:

    6. Section 76.1002 is amended by revising paragraphs (c)(2) (3), (5) and (6) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1002 Specific unfair practices prohibited.

    * * * * *

    (c) * * *

    (2) Served areas. No cable operator shall enter into any exclusive contracts, or engage in any practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming that meets the definition of a Regional Sports Network as defined in Sec. 76.1000(n) of this part with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, with respect to areas served by a cable operator, unless the Commission determines in accordance with paragraph (c)(4) of this section that such contract, practice, activity or arrangement is in the public interest.

    (3) Specific arrangements: Subdistribution agreements--(i) Unserved areas. No cable operator shall enter into any subdistribution agreement or arrangement for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, for distribution to persons in areas not served by a cable operator as of October 5, 1992, unless such agreement or arrangement complies with the limitations set forth in paragraph (c)(3)(iii) of this section.

    (ii) Served areas. No cable operator shall enter into any subdistribution agreement or arrangement for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming that meets the definition of a Regional Sports Network as defined in Sec. 76.1000(n) of this part with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, with respect to areas served by a cable operator, unless such agreement or arrangement complies with the limitations set forth in paragraph (c)(3)(iii) of this section.

    (iii) Limitations on subdistribution agreements. No cable operator engaged in subdistribution of satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming may require a competing multichannel video programming distributor to

    (A) Purchase additional or unrelated programming as a condition of such subdistribution; or

    (B) Provide access to private property in exchange for access to programming. In addition, a subdistributor may not charge a competing multichannel video programming distributor more for said programming than the satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor itself would be permitted to charge. Any cable operator acting as a subdistributor of satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming must respond to a request for access to such programming by a competing multichannel video programming distributor within fifteen (15) days of the request. If the request is denied, the competing multichannel video programming distributor must be permitted to negotiate directly with the satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor.

    * * * * *

    (5) Commission approval required. (i) Any cable operator, satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, or satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest must submit a ``Petition for Exclusivity'' to the Commission and receive approval from the Commission:

    (A) Prior to enforcing or entering into an exclusive contract, or practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, subject to paragraph (c)(2) of this section; and

    Page 24334

    (B) To preclude the filing of complaints alleging that an exclusive contract, or practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, with respect to areas served by a cable operator violates section 628(b) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and Sec. 76.1001(a) of this part, or section 628(c)(2)(B) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, and paragraph (b) of this section.

    (ii) The petition for exclusivity shall contain those portions of the contract relevant to exclusivity, including:

    (A) A description of the programming service;

    (B) The extent and duration of exclusivity proposed; and

    (C) Any other terms or provisions directly related to exclusivity or to any of the criteria set forth in paragraph (c)(4) of this section. The petition for exclusivity shall also include a statement setting forth the petitioner's reasons to support a finding that the contract is in the public interest, addressing each of the five factors set forth in paragraph (c)(4) of this section.

    (iii) Any competing multichannel video programming distributor affected by the proposed exclusivity may file an opposition to the petition for exclusivity within thirty (30) days of the date on which the petition is placed on public notice, setting forth its reasons to support a finding that the contract is not in the public interest under the criteria set forth in paragraph (c)(4) of this section. Any such formal opposition must be served on petitioner on the same day on which it is filed with the Commission.

    (iv) The petitioner may file a response within ten (10) days of receipt of any formal opposition. The Commission will then approve or deny the petition for exclusivity.

    (6) Sunset provision. The prohibition of exclusive contracts set forth in paragraph (c)(2) of this section shall cease to be effective on October 5, 2017, unless the Commission finds, during a proceeding to be conducted during the year preceding such date, that said prohibition continues to be necessary to preserve and protect competition and diversity in the distribution of video programming.

    * * * * *

    7. Section 76.1003 is amended by revising paragraph (e)(1) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1003 Program access proceedings.

    * * * * *

    (e) Answer. (1) Except as otherwise provided or directed by the Commission, any cable operator, satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor upon which a program access complaint is served under this section shall answer within twenty (20) days of service of the complaint, provided that the answer shall be filed within forty-five (45) days of service of the complaint if the complaint alleges a violation of section 628(b) of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, or Sec. 76.1001(a). To the extent that a cable operator, satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor expressly references and relies upon a document or documents in asserting a defense or responding to a material allegation, such document or documents shall be included as part of the answer.

    * * * * *

    Alternative 1:

    8. Section 76.1004 is amended by revising paragraph (b) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1004 Applicability of program access rules to common carriers and affiliates.

    * * * * *

    (b) Sections 76.1002(c)(1) through (3) shall be applied to a common carrier or its affiliate that provides video programming by any means directly to subscribers as follows: No common carrier or its affiliate that provides video programming directly to subscribers shall engage in any practice or activity or enter into any understanding or arrangement, including exclusive contracts, with a satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming that prevents a multichannel video programming distributor from obtaining such programming from any satellite cable programming vendor in which a common carrier or its affiliate has an attributable interest, or any satellite broadcasting vendor in which a common carrier or its affiliate has an attributable interest for distribution to persons in areas not served by a cable operator as of October 5, 1992.

    Alternative 2:

    9. Section 76.1004 is amended by revising paragraph (b) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1004 Applicability of program access rules to common carriers and affiliates.

    * * * * *

    (b) Sections 76.1002(c)(1) through (3) shall be applied to a common carrier or its affiliate that provides video programming by any means directly to subscribers in such a way that such common carrier or its affiliate shall be generally restricted from entering into an exclusive arrangement for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a common carrier or its affiliate has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a common carrier or its affiliate has an attributable interest, unless the arrangement pertains to an area served by a cable system as of October 5, 1992, and:

    (1) The Commission determines in accordance with Sec. 76.1002(c)(4) that such arrangement is in the public interest; or

    (2) Such arrangement pertains to a geographic area for which a petition for sunset has been granted pursuant to Sec. 76.1002(c)(7) of this part.

    Alternative 3:

    10. Section 76.1004 is amended by revising paragraph (b) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1004 Applicability of program access rules to common carriers and affiliates.

    * * * * *

    (b) Sections 76.1002(c)(1) through (3) shall be applied to a common carrier or its affiliate that provides video programming by any means directly to subscribers in such a way that such common carrier or its affiliate shall be generally restricted from entering into an exclusive arrangement for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming that meets the definition of a Regional Sports Network as defined in Sec. 76.1000(n) with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a common carrier or its affiliate has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which a common carrier or its affiliate has an attributable interest, unless the arrangement pertains to an area served by a cable system as of October 5, 1992, and the Commission determines in accordance with Sec. 76.1002(c)(4) that such arrangement is in the public interest.

    Alternative 1:

    11. Section 76.1507 is amended by removing and reserving paragraph (a)(2) and revising paragraphs (a)(3) and (b) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1507 Competitive access to satellite cable programming.

    (a) * * *

    (3) Section 76.1002(c)(3)(i) through (ii) shall only restrict the conduct of an open video system operator, its affiliate that provides video programming on its open video system and a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest, as follows: No open video system operator shall enter into any subdistribution agreement or arrangement for satellite cable

    Page 24335

    programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest for distribution to persons in areas not served by a cable operator as of October 5, 1992 unless such agreement or arrangement complies with the limitations set forth in Sec. 76.1002(c)(3)(ii).

    (b) No open video system programming provider in which a cable operator has an attributable interest shall engage in any practice or activity or enter into any understanding or arrangement, including exclusive contracts, with a satellite cable programming vendor or satellite broadcast programming vendor for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming that prevents a multichannel video programming distributor from obtaining such programming from any satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest, or any satellite broadcasting vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest for distribution to person in areas not served by a cable operator as of October 5, 1992.

    Alternative 2:

    12. Section 76.1507 is amended by revising paragraphs (a)(2) and (3) and paragraph (b)(2) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1507 Competitive access to satellite cable programming.

    (a) * * *

    (2) Section 76.1002(c)(2) shall only restrict the conduct of an open video system operator, its affiliate that provides video programming on its open video system and a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest, as follows: No open video system operator or its affiliate that provides video programming on its open video system shall enter into any exclusive contracts, or engage in any practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor, unless:

    (i) The Commission determines in accordance with Sec. 76.1002(c)(4) that such a contract, practice, activity or arrangement is in the public interest; or

    (ii) Such a contract, practice, activity or arrangement pertains to a geographic area for which a petition for sunset has been granted pursuant to Sec. 76.1002(c)(7).

    (3) Section 76.1002(c)(3)(i) through (ii) shall only restrict the conduct of an open video system operator, its affiliate that provides video programming on its open video system and a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest, as follows: No open video system operator shall enter into any subdistribution agreement or arrangement for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest, with respect to areas served or unserved by a cable operator, unless such agreement or arrangement complies with the limitations set forth in Sec. 76.1002(c)(3)(ii), except as provided in Sec. 76.1002(c)(3)(iii).

    (b) * * *

    (2) Enter into any exclusive contracts, or engage in any practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor, unless:

    (i) The Commission determines in accordance with Sec. 76.1002(c)(4) that such a contract, practice, activity or arrangement is in the public interest; or

    (ii) Such a contract, practice, activity or arrangement pertains to a geographic area for which a petition for sunset has been granted pursuant to Sec. 76.1002(c)(7).

    Alternative 3:

    13. Section 76.1507 is amended by revising paragraph (a)(2) through (3) and paragraph (b)(2) to read as follows:

    Sec. 76.1507 Competitive access to satellite cable programming.

    (a) * * *

    (2) Section 76.1002(c)(2) shall only restrict the conduct of an open video system operator, its affiliate that provides video programming on its open video system and a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest, as follows: No open video system operator or its affiliate that provides video programming on its open video system shall enter into any exclusive contracts, or engage in any practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming that meets the definition of a Regional Sports Network as defined in Sec. 76.1000(n) of this part with a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor, unless the Commission determines in accordance with Sec. 76.1002(c)(4) that such a contract, practice, activity or arrangement is in the public interest.

    (3) Section 76.1002(c)(3)(i) through (ii) shall only restrict the conduct of an open video system operator, its affiliate that provides video programming on its open video system and a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest, as follows:

    (i) Unserved areas. No open video system operator shall enter into any subdistribution agreement or arrangement for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming with a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest for distribution to persons in areas not served by a cable operator as of October 5, 1992 unless such agreement or arrangement complies with the limitations set forth in Sec. 76.1002(c)(3)(iii).

    (ii) Served areas. No open video system operator shall enter into any subdistribution agreement or arrangement for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming that meets the definition of a Regional Sports Network as defined in Sec. 76.1000(n) of this part with a satellite cable programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor in which an open video system operator has an attributable interest, with respect to areas served by a cable operator, unless such agreement or arrangement complies with the limitations set forth in Sec. 76.1002(c)(3)(iii).

    (b) * * *

    (2) Enter into any exclusive contracts, or engage in any practice, activity or arrangement tantamount to an exclusive contract, for satellite cable programming or satellite broadcast programming that meets the definition of a Regional Sports Network as defined in Sec. 76.1000(n) of this part with a satellite cable programming vendor in which a cable operator has an attributable interest or a satellite broadcast programming vendor, unless the Commission determines in

    Page 24336

    accordance with Sec. 76.1002(c)(4) that such a contract, practice, activity or arrangement is in the public interest.

    FR Doc. 2012-8991 Filed 4-20-12; 8:45 am

    BILLING CODE 6712-01-P

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT